\documentclass[authoryear,times,review,12pt,3p]{elsarticle} %special commands \newcommand{\ds}{\displaystyle} \newtheorem{lem}{Lemma}[section] \newtheorem{prop}{Proposition}[section] \newtheorem{defi}{Definition}[section] % Special Characters %model I \newcommand{\E}{\mathbb{E}} \newcommand{\cv}{c_{V}} \newcommand{\cs}{c_{S}} \newcommand{\piv}{\pi_{V}^I} \newcommand{\pis}{\pi_{S}^I} %model IG \newcommand{\pgv}{\pi_{V}^{IG}} \newcommand{\pgs}{\pi_{S}^{IG}} %model B \newcommand{\cvb}{c_{VB}} \newcommand{\csb}{c_{SB}} \newcommand{\pbs}{\pi_{S}^B} \newcommand{\pbv}{\pi_{V}^B} \newcommand{\eb}{e^B} \newcommand{\rb}{r^B} \newcommand{\pb}{p^B} \newcommand{\kb}{k^{B}} \newcommand{\pbb}{p^{B*}} %Model BG \newcommand{\pbgs}{\pi_{S}^{BG}} \newcommand{\pbgv}{\pi_{V}^{BG}} \newcommand{\rv}{r_{V}} \newcommand{\rvb}{r_{V}^B} \newcommand{\vso}{V_{SO}} \newcommand{\vvm}{V_{VM}} %Model B-c \newcommand{\pbcs}{\pi_{S}^{B-c}} \newcommand{\pbcv}{\pi_{V}^{B-c}} %Model BG-c \newcommand{\pbgcs}{\pi_{S}^{BG-c}} \newcommand{\pbgcv}{\pi_{V}^{BG-c}} %Model IA \newcommand{\pia}{\pi_{SC}^{IA}} \newcommand{\swia}{SW^{IA}} %Model BA \newcommand{\pba}{\pi_{SC}^{BA}} \newcommand{\swba}{SW^{BA}} %Model GA \newcommand{\pga}{\pi_{SC}^{GA}} \newcommand{\swga}{SW^{GA}} %Model BGA \newcommand{\pbga}{\pi_{SC}^{BGA}} \newcommand{\swbga}{SW^{BGA}} %refer to website \usepackage{url} % enable math symbols \usepackage[cmex10]{amsmath} \usepackage{mdwmath} \usepackage{amssymb} % mdwtab can be used to align equations and tables \usepackage{array} \usepackage{mdwtab} \usepackage{graphicx} % powful tools for table \usepackage{booktabs} \usepackage{tabularx} \usepackage{multirow} \usepackage{rotating} \usepackage[flushleft]{threeparttable} % change the position of figures or tables \usepackage{float} \usepackage{subcaption} % only used in revisions \usepackage{changes} % self-defined commands or simply \newcommand{\reffig}[1]{Figure~\ref{#1}} \newcommand{\reftab}[1]{Table~\ref{#1}} \newcommand{\refequ}[1]{Equation~(\ref{#1})} \newcommand{\refcstr}[1]{Constraint~\ref{#1}} \newcommand{\refsec}[1]{Section~\ref{#1}} \newcommand{\refalg}[1]{Algorithm~\ref{#1}} \newcommand{\reflem}[1]{Lemma~\ref{#1}} \newcommand{\refprop}[1]{Proposition~\ref{#1}} \newcommand{\refdefi}[1]{Definition~\ref{#1}} % change the journal name before submitting \journal{Journal of XYZ} \begin{document} \begin{frontmatter} \title{How to empower commercial satellite launch supply chain: Insurance, government subsidy or blockchain adoption?} \author[SEMUCAS]{Jichang Dong}\ead{jcdonglc@ucas.ac.cn} \author[SEMUCAS,SDCUCAS,BDCAS]{Yihan Jing}\ead{jingyihan18@mails.ucas.ac.cn} \author[SEMUCAS,BDCAS,MOECAS]{Zhou He\corref{Cor}}\ead{hezhou@ucas.ac.cn} \author[ZNU]{Ciwei Dong}\ead{ dongciwei@zuel.edu.cn} \address[SEMUCAS]{School of Economics and Management, University of Chinese Academy of Sciences, 3 Zhongguancun Nanyitiao, China} \address[SDCUCAS]{Sino-Danish College, University of Chinese Academy of Sciences, 80 Zhongguancun East Road, Beijing 100190, China.} \address[BDCAS]{Key Laboratory of Big Data Mining and Knowledge Management, Chinese Academy of Sciences, 80 Zhongguancun East Road, Beijing 100190, China.} \address[MOECAS]{MOE Social Science Laboratory of Digital Economic Forecasts and Policy Simulation at UCAS, 3 Zhongguancun Nanyitiao, China} \address[ZNU]{School of Business Administration, Zhongnan University of Economics and Law, Wuhan 430073, China} \cortext[Cor]{Corresponding author. Tel.: +86 10 88250000; fax: +86 10 88250000.} \begin{abstract} The commercial launch industry is booming with possible launch failures, which can cause enormous loss for both vehicle manufacturer and satellite operator. To hedge such risks and reduce potential costs, they often buy launch insurance from financial companies, and/or seek possible subsidy from government-backed schemes. Recently, the innovative blockchain technology has been adopted by satellite launch supply chains to enhance data sharing, improve workflow efficiency, and thus reduce launch risks. However, very little research has been done on how these players interact, make decisions, and how the satellite launch supply chain (SLSC) can be empowered by insurance, government subsidy or blockchain adoption. In this paper, we propose several Stackelberg games to examine the SLSC cases with launch insurance (Model I), with insurance \& government subsidies (Model IG), with blockchain-embedded insurance (Model B), and with blockchain-embedded insurance \& government subsidies (Model BG). We investigate the optimal launch price, retail price, and the effort (for improving launch success probability) expressions by deriving models. Furthermore, we explore the conditions for optimal allocation of government subsidies and the cost thresholds for adopting blockchain technology by analyzing the equilibrium outcomes. We find that if the government wants to form a virtuous circle and optimize the allocation of funds, it should subsidize satellite operators that use cost-effective vehicles for launch activities rather than providing unconditional subsidies. In addition, we also find that the subsidy does not benefit consumers, but blockchain can. Once the blockchain technology is adopted, contract prices go up, the vehicle manufacturer exerts more effort, and the premium rate always is lower as the launch missions become more efficient and believable. Besides, the adoption of blockchain technology can also improve the benefits from government subsidies. Moreover, when the satellite operator chooses an inexpensive launch vehicle, the cost-advantage blockchain-embedded platform benefits all participants. Finally, coupling these findings, we further discuss the managerial implications for the commercial space launch market. \end{abstract} \begin{keyword} Satellite launch \sep insurance\sep government subsidy \sep blockchain \sep commercial launch supply chain \end{keyword} % \section{Highlights} % (1) This paper investigates the implement of blockchain technologies in the commercial launch industry, which can effectively improve the efficient of data flow.\par % (2)Two mathematical models have been built: insurance model and blockchain-embedded model. \par % (3) Uncover the threshold of using blockchain for each participant.\par % (4) Reveal the adoption of blockchain can improve supply chain members to achieve a win-win situation. \par \end{frontmatter} % usually, add a new page before introduction \newpage \section{Introduction}\label{sec:introduction} \subsection{Background} Man-made satellites can collect extensive and valuable data which can be used in archaeology, cartography, environmental monitoring, meteorology, and reconnaissance applications. Space is no longer confined to government and military agencies like NASA, but open to private companies since 1980s, thanks to the changes of space laws and regulatory regime \citep{OECD2014}. On Dec.3th 2013, the SES-8 satellite was successfully delivered by a Falcon 9 launch vehicle made by SpaceX, a private company founded in 2002 shaking up the competitive satellite launch industry by offering lower cost launches than their competitors \citep{spacex}. This successful launch significantly promotes the global space industry, the total revenue of which reaches \$386 billion by 2021, according to the Satellite Industry Association \citep{Space2022}. The commercial satellite industry put a record 1,713 commercial satellites into orbit for the fourth consecutive year, an increase of more than 40\% compared to 2020. Behind such vigorous development, the launch failure risk can not ignored by the companies in satellite launch supply chain (SLSC). Once the launch fails, the loss for both vehicle manufacturer and satellite operator is enormous. To hedge this risk, there are three solutions in practice. First, space insurance emerged. Insurance companies like \textit{Global Aerospace} have been providing different space insurance services, which can be roughly divided into four types according to satellite project phases: pre-launch insurance\footnote{ Pre-launch insurance covers damage to a satellite or launch vehicle during the construction, transportation, and processing phases prior to launch.}, launch insurance\footnote{Launch insurance covers losses of a satellite occurring during the launch phase of a project. It insures against complete launch failures as well as the failure of a launch vehicle to place a satellite in the proper orbit.}, in-orbit insurance\footnote{In-orbit policies insure satellites for in-orbit technical problems and damages once a satellite has been placed by a launch vehicle in its proper orbit.}, and launch plus life insurance\footnote{Third-party liability and government property insurances protect launch service providers and their customers in the event of public injury or government property damage, respectively, caused by launch or mission failure.}. Among them, the launch insurance is most popular because the launch phase is the riskiest activity and the damage is often catastrophic \citep{Suchodolski2018, Gould2000, Kunstadter2020}. With more and more satellite operators realizing the importance of launch insurance, nearly half of satellite launches are insured \citep{Hussain2021}. Second, the government subsidized. Since the commercial industry promotes the development of high technologies, some governments have introduced policies to subsidize the SLSC. For example, the \textit{Beijing Bureau of Economy and Information Technology} subsidized commercial space enterprises that engage in the production and manufacture of vehicles and satellites, and encouraged them to establish headquarters, sales and operation in Beijing. In addition, the Unites States not only provided subsidy for launch liability insurance but also awarded the commercial companies directly. Third, new technology helped. Blockchain, a disruptive technology that facilitates data sharing and trust building, has been adopted by the SLSC companies, such as \textit{SpaceChain}, \textit{IBM} and \textit{Cloud Constellation Corporation}. It is used to share the critical data (e.g., contracts, test results) among trusted parties to make the workflow (e.g., approvals, auditing) more efficient and visible, so that the launch failure risk can be reduced as much as possible \citep{Zheng2021}. Each solution above introduces new entity (insurance company, government, and blockchain service provider) with different interest into the SLSC. Hence, both the private companies and government are keen to understand the impacts of different solutions on SLSC performance. \subsection{Research questions and key findings} This paper aims to study the following research questions (RQ): RQ1. How to analytically model the interactions among key entities in SLSC, namely vehicle manufacturer (VM), satellite operator (SO) and insurance company (IC)? What is the optimal decision for each entity? RQ2. How to analyze the impact of government subsidy on the optimal decisions in SLSC? RQ3. Is blockchain worth adopting to the SLSC? How to understand its impacts on the optimal decisions? To investigate RQ1, we propose a benchmark model with three entities, called Model I. This model is extended as Model IG to study RQ2 by considering government subsidy. Next, the blockchain technology is introduced into both models as Model B and BG. Comparing the optimal decisions in these four models, we obtain the following results: \begin{enumerate} [(1)] \item Government subsidies can be used to incentivize SO to pay higher launch prices, so that the VM have the motivation to increase the probability of successful launches, and the overall social welfare (total profit of all players) also increases. \item The impacts caused by blockchain technology and government subsidy are similar; the difference is threefold: for SO, blockchain adoption (if the cost is low) increases its data retail price and profit; for VM, its profit depends on the cost of blockchain adoption and vehicle manufacturing; for satellite data customer, its surplus increases. \item @@@ try to add another finding/result. No insurance-related results? \end{enumerate} @@@carefully enumerate your contributions The rest of this paper is organized as follows. \refsec{sec:review} reviews four related research streams. \refsec{sec:models} establishes the benchmark case with launch insurance (Model I), and introduces government subsidies into an extended case (Model IG). \refsec{sec:blockchain} examines the impact of blockchain adoption in the SLSC under two scenarios, one with launch insurance (Model B) and one with government-subsidized launch insurance (Model GB). \refsec{sec:extensions} relaxes some assumptions to generate new findings. \refsec{sec:conclusions} concludes this paper and suggests potential topics for future research. \section{Literature review}\label{sec:review} Our paper is closely related to four research streams: supply chain insurance, space supply chain management, blockchain, and government subsidies. \subsection{Supply chain insurance} Supply chain insurance is a sub-stream of supply chain finance which is extensively studied in today's FinTech era \citep{Zhao2015,Xu2018,Wang2021b}. Among the many types of commercial insurance, the one most similar to the space launch insurance in this paper is business interruption insurance (BI insurance). In management practice, companies can utilize BI insurance to hedge against risks. However, it must be pointed out that the purchase cost of BI insurance is high, and it is at the cost of sacrificing current profits to achieve risk aversion. If no interruption occurs during the insurance period, this premium will become a sunk cost for the enterprise. At this point, facing the high cost of current payment and the small probability of large economic losses in the future, the trade-off between risks and benefits becomes an important issue to be studied and solved in theory and practice. According to the different sources of risk, BI insurance can be divided into two categories: risk of endogenous disruption which mainly comes from within the supply chain (e.g., inventory shortages, cooperator's bankruptcy, transportation delays); and risk of exogenous disruption which Mainly from the external environment of the supply chain (e.g., Natural disaster risk, social risk and economic risk) \citep{Sodhi2012a, Heckmann2015}. (1) Hedging endogenous risks. \citet{Lin2010} compared insurance contract with revenue sharing contract according to different agents' risk aversion based on the news-vendor model. With the presence of inventory risk, \cite{Dong2012} applied BI insurance to a single-period product-inventory operation management. Based on \cite{Dong2012}, \cite{Dong2018} considered the preparation strategy. By examining a two-stage model, the effects of inventory, preparedness, and BI insurance on the product chain are comparatively analyzed. In the after-sales service context, \cite{Qin2020} constructed a principal-agent model by combining the insurance options with after-sales service contracts to reduce operational risk (e.g., machine failure). Specifically, they consider two main forms of contracts: resource-based contract and performance-based contract. Besides, \citet{Wang2021} also discussed which contract is better for supply chain partners between the advanced payment contract, penalty contract, and time insurance contract in the express delivery supply chain. (2) Hedging exogenous risk. \cite{LodreeJr2008} designed an insurance policy framework to quantify the risks and benefits. \cite{Balcik2019} proposed a cooperative pre-deployment strategy between countries responding to hurricane disasters. The authors determined the location and quantity of relief supplies to be stored based on a stochastic programming model and developed a dataset for the network with real-world data. \cite{Yu2021} considered the interrupt probability of the supply chain, and illustrate that business interruption insurance increases the profit of each participant. \cite{Brusset2018} constructed a weather index, so that entrepreneurial risk can be transferred to other risk-takers through insurance or options contracts. %Similar to these researches, our paper also adopts the insurance contract to hedge the interrupt risk while the focal point is in the space launch supply chain, which is remarkable for technical complexity, high quality \& reliability requirements, and colossal failure losses. %However, we also combine the blockchain technology with supply chain management which is timely and important. \subsection{Space supply chain management} There is a large body of literature dealing with the supply chain. However, only a few of them applies to the space industry. According to the available literature, the development of space supply chain is broadly divided into two phases. (1) Around 1950's, scholars began to pay attention to the space logistics which mainly serving the supply and re-supply during the space exploration. \cite{Braun1954} mentioned the the necessity of space logistics in the Mars project and he also pointed out that the logistics support, which is a main contributor to success or failure, is an important part of the project. \cite{Follett1965} gave the definition of the space logistics as a transportation of person and material from earth to outer places in space which involving the supply and re-supply of the exploration, and the maintenance of vehicles and bases. During this stage, the main used logistics supply models are Backpack Model and Scheduled Re-supply Model. To meet the requirements of the feasibility, reliability, affordability and maintenance of space explorations, \cite{Antol1999} combined the advantages of the above two models and proposed the establishment of the International Space Station as a free flyer servicing node. \cite{Cuplin2000} investigated the ability of satellite serving to do on-orbit considering the design objectives of "better, faster, cheaper". \cite{Gavish2004} Scholars exploit a Markov decision model solved by dynamic programming methods to find the optimal policy for satellite launches, thus achieving cost savings for Low-earth orbit satellite system operators. (2) Until 2006, the concept of space supply chain \cite{Fayez2006} was put forward, marking a new stage in the researching development. In this stage, scholars not only considered the materials delivering narrowly, but also integrated the data, information, crew, knowledge and capital flow into the space supply chain \citep{Galluzzi2006}, which is more expansively. Numerous academic conferences on the topic of space supply chain operations were held during that year, thus, 2006 was also called The Year of Space Logistics by The International Society of Logistics. In this stage, a number of research institutions represented by NASA, MIT and Jet Propulsion Laboratory have first conducted systematic and comprehensive research on space logistics which have been in the leading position in the world \citep{Cheng2009}. To visually simulate the flow of space vehicles and supplies through the interplanetary logistics network, MIT researchers developed the SpaceNet which is a simulation and optimization software \citep{Lee2008}. Based on NASA project practices, \cite{Evans2006} discussed the impact of traditional supply chain models on the efficiency of space supply chain operations, such as such as SCOR Model, Lean – Six Sigma, and Capability Maturity Model. Besides, to optimize the transfer of supplies in space, \cite{Taylor2006} developed a heuristic optimization algorithm by extending the terrestrial logistics model and incorporate the astrodynamic relationships. \cite{Brandimarte2013} constructed a MILP model subject to resource constraints. Specifically, the paper investigates the scheduling of different launchers and different mission profiles to schedule Low-earth orbit satellite. \cite{Zhang2015} developed a multi-objective mixed integer planning model for the collaborative optimization of multi-center multi-satellite launch missions based on the nondominated sorting genetic algorithm II. In this paper, they focus on the optimization objectives of minimum launch cost and minimum launch failure probability to solve the collaborative programming problem for a large amount of satellite launch missions. \cite{Chen2021} develops a flexibility management framework for space logistics mission planning under uncertainty through decision rules and multistage stochastic programming. In addition to articles focusing on operations research, the business issues in space supply chain operation are also worthy of study with the commercial space entities emerging \cite{Dewicki2010}. Therefore, a number of scholars have recently conducted studies around operation management which are more relevant to our paper. \cite{Tang2014} provided a framework to balance cost, time and risk in the aircraft supply chain. \cite{Wooten2018} examined the space industry's operation management, which involves manufacturing operations, supply chain management, and sustainable operations. Besides, they also outlined the challenges and essential questions related to stakeholders. \cite{Raghunath2021} discussed the challenges that commercial space operation faces from a business perspective. Furthermore, \cite{Guo2021} comprehensively analyzed the global aerospace industry's current situation and future development from the upstream supply chain, midstream production chain, and downstream application chain. In addition, \cite{Donelli2021} considered the profitability and efficiency during the aircraft manufacturing and supply chain. The paper proposed a model-based approach to optimal the multiple-choice. % As review literature, most papers target SCM in space give the mathematical model from optimizing logistics, even the system flow. While our paper builds models from the business angle, we concentrate on the game theory between participants during the launch activity. \subsection{Blockchain technology support supply chain management} As a “trust ledger”, blockchain has overwhelming advantage of data storage such as openness, transparency, tampering, and traceability, which make it possible to manipulate higher quality data \citep{Choi2019}, improving the supply chain efficiency and so on \citep{Chod2020}. According to its characters, \cite{Queiroz2019,Wang2019,Babich2020, Li2022} gave the review of this topic.\par Besides, more and more scholars have begun to study the application of blockchain in the supply chain. (1) Inside the supply chain, (i) in upriver of supply chain, blockchain technology facilitates the flow of raw materials from the suppliers \citep{ Naydenova2017, Nash2016}; (ii) in the midstream, it promotes the exchange of manufacture information and design smart contracts between participants in the supply chain upstream and downstream and achieve coordination eventually \citep{Moise2018, Hilary2022, Chod2020,Korpela2017,Wang2021a}. (2) Outside the supply chain, (i) face the third party, it provides an innovative way for the capital constraint companies to finance \citep{Choi2020,Choi2021}; (ii) face the market, it helps products to fight counterfeits, earn trust of customers and win company reputation in the market \citep{Pun2021, Shen2021,Fan2020}.\par Regarding our topic, this article mainly refers to articles on the application of blockchain in the space supply chain. \cite{Luo2020} adopted blockchain technology to enhance systems security and examined its affection on the government’s penalty system. \cite{Adhikari2020} gave a clearly analysis on the implementation of blockchain in the area of space cybersecurity framework against global positioning system spoofing. \cite{Clark2020} developed a secure system by leveraging the distributed ledger technology of blockchain for satellite networks. This system achieves reduced latency when transmitting data across constellations and reduces the burden in terms of quality, power and cost for all users. \cite{Zheng2021} studied a three-tier space supply chain under the decision-making problem and investigated how blockchain technology optimizes decisions based on information sharing. Moreover, \cite{HylandWood2020} examined three potential blockchain properties applied in space: real-time communication during the interplanetary space operating and operations realm of the solar system. \cite{Li2021} developed a framework based on blockchain technology which consists of an application layer, a contract and consensus layer, a data layer and a network layer to management the information of rocket and satellite launch. %However, different from them, this article's focal point is on launching a service supply chain supported by fintech ( blockchain-embedded insurance) to facilitate launching risks and contract pricing. \subsection{Government subsidies} Government interventions in supply chain management include legislation \citep{Gouda2016, Zhang2018}, penalties \citep{Xiao2018,Luo2020}, subsidies \citep{Guo2019,Xiao2020,Jung2020} and taxes \citep{Xu2018a,Chen2020}. The stream of research closest to our work is exploring the adoption of government subsidies to promote industry growth or to support firms through difficult times. In order to improve the social welfare and the manufacturers' profits, different types of subsidy programs has been launched by governments, such as subsidies to consumers, manufacturers, or both \cite{Yu2018}. The authors of this article reveal the influencing factors that determine the optimal structure of government subsidy programs. They find that governments can develop subsidy programs involving multiple competing manufacturers to improve consumer welfare. However, the government subsidy system is not always effective. \cite{Hsu2019} find that the quality subsidy offered to the farmers quality subsidies provided to farmers may reduce not only the quality of dairy products, but also the profitability of companies. \cite{Berenguer2017} analyze the effectiveness of subsidies on a for-profit or a not-for profit firm in inducing consumption. Their study shows that the incentive to a not-for-profit counterpart is more stronger than to a for-profit firm to encourage consumption. Besides, \cite{Bai2021} investigate the design of trade-in subsidy programs by capturing the essence of the interaction between the government, the manufacturer, and consumers. They find that compared with a fixed-amount subsidy, a shared subsidy program in which government subsidies are proportional to manufacturer rebates is more effective in stimulating consumers to trade-in. %In the same vein as the above literature, we also explore the effectiveness of government subsidies in supply chain operations. %However, the difference is that we focus on the commercial space supply chain to explore how subsidy systems can be implemented to leverage its value. \subsection{Contributions of this paper} To sum, in this section we have reviewed four research streams, comparing to the literature from these topics, our paper's contributions are as follows: (1) Inspired by \cite{Wooten2018}'s study on space industry operation management, we theoretically investigate space supply chain management from the perspective of business, which not only enriches the study of space operations but also expands the research field of supply chain finance. (2) To portray the hedging risk strategy, we refer to \cite{Tang2018}. However, different from their models, we also consider the role of insurance and government subsidies to deal with launch risk. (3) Although numbers of scholars have researched the application of blockchain technology in operation management, few have explored its impact on SLSC decisions. Based on real-world observation \citep{Altaf2019}, we adopt blockchain technology in launch activity and theoretically analyze its value in SLSC with reference to \cite{Luo2020}. (4) In terms of modeling, we have innovatively constructed a three-stage Stackelberg game model which characterizes the high-risk, high-loss nature of SLSC. %The insights not only contribute to the literature in operation management but also advance the industrial knowledge regarding blockchain launch platforms.\par \section{Benchmark case} \label{sec:models} Consider an engineer-to-order supply chain consisting of one vehicle manufacturer (VM, he), one satellite operator (SO, she) and an insurance company (IC, it). As shown in \reffig{fig:sequence}, to launch the satellite successfully, the SO usually conducts a series analyses to choose the vehicle and design the launch service contract with launch price $l$ and prepay ratio $\alpha$. Once the satellite is on-track, the SO will pay VM last part $(1-\alpha)p$ and she will obtain income from sailing satellite data. Without loss generality, consumers possess a stochastic valuation $u$ towards the satellite data, which follows a distribution $f(u)$. Following most literature, we set $f(u)$ follows a uniform distribution with a rage of $0-1$, denoted by $U[0,1]$. To avoid facing messy mathematics, we normalize the consumer population as $1$. % the SO has already signed contracts future servicing missions at income $F$ before launching \citep{SpaceFund2022}, which rely on satellite service to function. So the satellite income also is one factor that SO needs to consider while designing the launch contract, which is an indicator of her risk resistance \citep{Li2010}. \par As common in launch activity, our models capture two typical features in the space supply chain. First, the launch activity is risky, which means there is a probability for the satellite operating in its final orbital position. The VM can improve the probability of mission success (aka reliability) by exerting costly efforts (e.g., improving technologies, equipment or processes) \citep{Bailey2020, Kunstadter2020}. Following \cite{Tang2018}, we scale the base launch success probability to 0. To increase the probability from 0 to $e$, where $e \in (0, 1)$, the VM needs to exert effort associated with a disutility (cost of effort) $ke^2$ with $k > 0$. The setting of such a disutility is common in many models.\par Notedly, a launch failure is costly to all involved parties. For the SO, she will lost her satellite and the income. For the VM, what he will face is not only the current contract loss but also the damage of his reputation and future business as well as financing. To reflect the VM's additional loss, a penalty denoted by $\theta$ is adopted into the profit function. %\textcolor{red}{cite:Williams-Robert-COVERING-THE-INCREASED-LIABILITY-OF-NEW-LAUNCH-MARKETS.pdf} Considering the launch risk, it is natural that SO attempts to purchase launch insurance before launching to hedge risks. IC designs the launch insurance according to the analyses of conducting serious technological analyses of satellite and the VM. Once the launch fails, the IC usually pays pro rate compensation. We assume the claim covers $\beta$ of the whole loss including the cost of satellite and the prepay price. We summarize the notation used throughout the paper in \reftab{tab:Parameters}. \begin{table}[htbp] \scriptsize \caption{\label{tab:Parameters} Notation} \centering \begin{threeparttable} \begin{tabular}{ll} % lcr: left, center, right \toprule Variable & Remark\\ \midrule Model I & Satellite launch supply chain with insurance\\ Model IG& Satellite launch supply chain with government-subsidized insurance \\ Model B & Blockchain-embedded satellite launch supply chain with insurance \\ Model BG & Blockchain-embedded satellite launch supply chain with government-subsidized insurance \\ $p$ & The satellite data retail price \\ $l$ & The launching service price \\ $\alpha$ & The upfront payment ratio \\ $e$& The “rate of successful launch ”, which is the same as “the level of effort the VM exerting” in this paper \\ $k$& The cost coefficient of effort\\ $r$ &The premium rate \\ $\beta$& The claim ratio\\ $g$& The government-subsidized launch insurance premium rates\\ $c_i$& The cost of vehicle $(i= V)$ or satellite $(i= S)$ \\ %\textcolor{red}{Payment for a launch is usually subdivided in several installments. A first rate will usually be charged upon reservation of a certain flight opportunity, while the second one is due upon launch service agreement signature. As soon as the ICD is finalized, a third rate applies and the final part is charged when the launch has been performed.} $\theta$ & The penalty of a failed launch for VM\\ $k$ & The effort cost factor\\ $\pi_i$ & The profit of vehicle manufacture$(i= V)$ or satellite operator $(i= S)$ or insurance company $(i=I)$\\ $CS$& The consumer surplus\\ $SW$& The social welfare\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \begin{tablenotes} \item[a] Subscripts $S$, $V$ and $I$ are the indices of SO, VM and IC respectively. \item[b] Superscript $I$, $IG$, $B$ and $BG$ to describe function and decisions in model I, model IG, model B and model BG respectively. \end{tablenotes} \end{threeparttable} \end{table} % TODO: \usepackage{graphicx} required \begin{figure}[H] \centering \includegraphics[width=1\linewidth]{sequences.pdf} \caption{Sequence of events. SO :the satellite operator; VM: the vehicle manufacture; IC: the insurance company. } \label{fig:sequence} \end{figure} \subsection{Model I: Satellite launch supply chain with insurance } \label{sec:modeli} Acting as the Stackelberg leader, the SO sets the contract terms and the VM, as the follower, decides whether to accept the contract. Without loss of generality, we focus on the following contract: the SO pays the VM a certain $\alpha$ of launch price $l$ upfront when launch services are procured. \citep{Andrews2011,Barschke2020} Furthermore, when the launch is successful, the VM then receives the balance of the payment $(1-\alpha)*l$ for services or $0$ otherwise. Concerning risk, the SO buys the launch insurance with the premium rate $r$ to compensate the loss if the launch failed. \reffig{fig:sequence} shows the sequence of events corresponding to the game model. Therefore, the market demand and payoff function, $D^I$ and $\pis$, faces by the SO can be measured as follows: \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:id} % \left\{ \begin{aligned} D^I &= 1 \int_{p}^{1}{f\left( u \right) \mathrm{d} u}= 1-p\\ \end{aligned} % \right. \end{eqnarray} \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:iso:payoff} % \left\{ \begin{aligned} \max_{l,p} \E [\pis(l, p, e, r)] &= epD^I -[\alpha + e(1-\alpha) ]l - r (\cs + \alpha l) + (1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l)- \cs,\\ % s.t.~pD &\geq \cs + l \end{aligned} % \right. \end{eqnarray} As shown, $\pis$ consists of five parts: (1) the income she can obtain once the satellite works in orbit $epD^I$; (2) the expect launch service price $[\alpha+e(1-\alpha)]l$; (3) the premium for the launch insurance $ r (\cs + \alpha l)$; (4) the compensate she will get once the launch failed $(1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l) $. (5) the cost of building the satellite $ \cs$. Without loss of generality, the satellite income covers its building and launch cost; i.e., the SO sets a contract only when $pD^I\geq\cs + l $.\par As depicted in \reffig{fig:sequence}, the VM accepts a contract with price $l$ and receives the prepayment $\alpha*l$ from the SO, then he manufactures the rocket which cost $c_v$. If the vehicle launch successfully, he receives the last $(1-\alpha )*l$ from the SO. If launching is failed, the VM not only receives no payment but also suffers penalty which monetized as $\theta$ . Therefore, the VM’s objective is to maximize his expected payoff $\piv$ as follows: \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:vm:payoff} % \left\{ \begin{aligned} \max_e \E [\piv(l, p, e)] &=[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha) ]l - (1 - e) \theta - (ke^2 + \cv),\\ s.t.~\piv &\geq 0 \end{aligned} % \right. \end{eqnarray} As shown, $\piv$ consists of three parts: (1) the prepaid income and expected gain upon successful launch $[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha) ]l$, (2) the expected loss of failure penalty in the event of launch failure $(1 - e) \theta$, and (3) the cost of effort and vehicle $ke^2 + \cv$. The non-negative profit constraint ensures the profitability of launch successfully; otherwise, the VM will quit the cooperation. \subsubsection{The VM’s effort} We now solve the Stackelberg game as depicted in \reffig{fig:sequence} using backward induction. First, given any launch price $l$, by considering the first-order condition of \refequ{eq:vm:payoff}, the VM’s best response is given as: \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:ei} %\nonumber e(l)&=\frac{(1-\alpha)l+\theta}{2k},\\ ~s.t.&0l_{VA}$) } & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ (i.e., $I_{VA} \geq l_S$ ) } \\ \midrule Effort of VM exerting $e^*$& $\frac{\phi}{16(1-\alpha)k}$ & $\frac{\omega-\alpha k }{(1-\alpha)k}$ \\ Launch price $l^*$& $l^*=l_{S}=\frac{\phi-8\theta(1-\alpha)}{8(1-\alpha)^2}$& $ l^*=l_{VA}= \frac{2\omega-2\alpha k-(1-\alpha) \theta}{(1-\alpha)^2}$\\ Retail price $p^*$& $\frac{1}{2}$& $\frac{1}{2}$\\ Premium rate $r^*$& $\beta(1-\frac{\phi}{16(1-\alpha)k})$& $\beta\frac{k-\omega}{(1-\alpha)k}$\\ SO's profit $\pis$& $\frac{\phi^2}{128(1-\alpha)^2k}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha} -\cs$& $\frac{(\omega-\alpha k)(\phi+8\alpha k-8\omega)}{4(1-\alpha )^2k}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha}-\cs$\\ VM's profit $\piv$& $\frac{\phi^2+32\alpha k\phi}{256(1-\alpha)^2k}-\frac{ \theta}{1-\alpha}-\cv$& $0$\\ Consumer surplus $CS^I$& $\frac{1}{8}$& $\frac{1}{8}$&\\ Social welfare $SW^I$& $\frac{3\phi^2+32\alpha k\phi}{256(1-\alpha)^2k}- \theta-\cs-\cv+\frac{1}{8}$& $\frac{(\omega-\alpha k)(\phi+8\alpha k-8\omega)}{4(1-\alpha )^2k}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha}-\cs+\frac{1}{8}$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \begin{tablenotes} \item To avoid complicated writing, we define $\phi=(1-\alpha)(1+4\theta)-8\alpha k$, $\omega=\sqrt{(1-\alpha)^2k\cv+\alpha ^2k^2-(1-\alpha)k\theta}$. \end{tablenotes} \end{table*} Note that there are two cases in our equilibrium result that $\cv\phi$. The premium rate $r$ will decrease, affected by government subsidy. (ii) When $\cv\geq H(\alpha)$, the successful launch probability, launch price, and the premium rate do not affect by the government subsidy. (iii) No matter the situation, the retail price doesn't change, which means the government subsidy program doesn't affect the market retail price. We will talk about the difference between model I and model IG in detail in \refsec{sec:value_g}. We now report the sensitivity analysis performing as shown in \reftab{tab:modeli_and_ig_sensitivity}. We find that the results of Model IG and Model I were very similar, but with three difference. Firstly, if the cost coefficient of effort $k$ increases, (i) when $0e^I$, $r^{IG}l^I$ if and only if $\cvH(\alpha)$), government subsidies will not be able to form the above positive feedback closed loop in the market. \begin{prop} \label{prop:value_profit_g} Given $\alpha,~ k,~\theta,~g$: \begin{enumerate}[(i)] \item $\pgs>\pis$, $SW^{IG}>SW^I$.\par \item $\pgv>\piv$ if and only if $\cv\phi$, the successful launch probability, the launch price are higher than in Model I; and the premium rate is lower than in Model I. (ii) When $\cv\geq H(\alpha)$, the equilibrium outcomes are not neat and cannot be directly compared which we will conduct analyze in detail in \refsec{sec:value_b}. (iii) Although the retail price is higher compared with Model I, the consumer surplus in increase with the implementation of BCT. Notedly, the consumer surplus is only related to $b$, not to the cost of the blockchain. Therefore, as long as blockchain technology is adopted, the consumer surplus can be improved. As the sensitivity outcomes shown in \reftab{tab:modeli_and_ig_sensitivity} we now conduct the analysis. \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:modeli_and_b_sensitivity} Sensitivity analyses for Model I and Model B.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}} \toprule & {Model}&{Situation}&{$e^*$}&{$r^*$}&{$l^*$}&{$p^*$} &{$\pi_S$}&{$\pi_V$}&{$CS$}&{$SW$} \\ \midrule $k \uparrow$ & Model I &{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & $\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$: $kk_2$, which means BCT raises the threshold of the SO to change the trend of her profits. (ii) Secondly, if the failed-launch penalty$\theta$ increase, when $\cv\theta_{V3}$ and $\theta>\theta_{W3}$ both profits of them will decrease. (iii) If the benefits that blockchain brings to consumers $b$ increases, (a) when $\cv0$& $-\beta\frac{k[(1+b)^2+4\theta]-\kb(1+4\theta)}{16k\kb}<0$& $\frac{(1-\alpha)(b^2+2b)+8\alpha(k-\kb)}{8(1-\alpha)^2}>0$& $\frac{b}{2}>0$\\ &{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }& $\frac{k\mu-\kb\omega}{k\kb(1-\alpha)}>0$& $-\beta$$\frac{k\mu-\kb \omega}{k\kb(1-\alpha)}<0$& $\frac{2(\mu-\omega)+2\alpha(k-\kb)}{(1-\alpha)^2}>0$& $\frac{b}{2}>0$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \end{table*} \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:value_profit_b} Values of BCT on members' payoffs.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}} \toprule &{Situation}&{$V_{ SO}^B$}&{$V_{VM}^B$}&{$V_{CS}^B$}&{$V_{SW}^B$} \\ \midrule Value & {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & $\frac{k\eta ^2-\kb \phi^2}{128k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}-\csb$& $\frac{k\eta ^2-\kb \phi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\eta-\phi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}-\cvb$& $\frac{b^2+2b}{8}$& $\frac{3k\eta ^2-3\kb \phi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\eta-\phi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b}{8}-\csb-\cvb$\\ &{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }& $\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}-\csb$& $0$& $\frac{b^2+2b}{8}$& $\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b}{8}-\csb$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \end{table*} \begin{prop} \label{prop:value_decision_b} Given $\alpha$, $\kb$, $k$, $\theta$, $b$: $e^{B}>e^I$, $r^{B}l^I$, $p^{B}>p^I$. \end{prop} \refprop{prop:value_decision_b} gives us four claims. Firstly, the optimal effort exerted by VM is higher after adopting blockchain technology, which directly leads to a higher launch success probability directly. That also implies that BCT helps to improve work efficiency. Secondly, the premium rate decreasing due to the successful launch probability increase. Thirdly, the launch price is higher with the support of BCT, mainly because the probability of successful launch increases and the SO is willing to pay higher fees. Fourthly, as shown the change of $e$, $r$, and $l$ are similar to \refprop{prop:value_decision_g}, however, the retail price in Model B increases after implementing BCT which is different from \refprop{prop:value_decision_g}. It is due to the higher utility that BCT bring to customers, so they are more willing to pay a higher retail price. \begin{prop} \label{prop:value_profit_b} Given $\alpha$, $\kb$, $k$, $\theta$, $b$: \begin{enumerate}[(i)] \item If $\csb ~ \big( \begin{smallmatrix} < \\ =\\> \end{smallmatrix} \big)~ \min\{\frac{k\eta ^2-\kb \phi^2}{128k\kb (1-\alpha)^2},\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}\}$, then we have: $V_{ SO}^B~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~0$; \item When $\cv \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~\frac{k\eta ^2-\kb \phi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\eta-\phi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2} $ , then we have: $V_{VM}^B~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ 0$; when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, $V_{VM}^B \equiv 0$ \item $V_{CS}^B>0$ \item When $\cv \end{smallmatrix} \big) \frac{3k\eta ^2-3\kb \phi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\eta-\phi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b}{8} $, then we have $V_{SW}^B ~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ 0$; when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, if $\csb ~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} < \\ =\\> \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ \frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b}{8}$, then we have $V_{SW}^B ~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ 0$. \end{enumerate} \end{prop} As shown above, \refprop{prop:value_profit_b} gives us four neat findings. Firstly, it gives the threshold of blockchain cost for SO, indicating that if the cost of implementing blockchain technology is high, then launching through the BCT platform is not profitable. That is because the loss of paying for blockchain cannot be offset by the benefits of improving the quality of data flow and higher retail income. Actually, there are two different thresholds for the SO to decide whether implement BCT in two situations. However, once BCT costs are pretty low, it is always profitable for the SO to use blockchain. Secondly, it also gives the threshold and condition for VM using blockchain. When $\cv\psi$ leading to numerator increases, thus the successful launch probability $e$ and the launch price $l$ are higher than in Model IG; and the premium rate $r$ is lower compared with Model IG. (ii) Although the retail price $p$ is higher compared with Model IG, the consumer surplus eventually increase due to a greater increase in market demand with the adoption of BCT. Noted, the consumer surplus is only related to $b$, not to the cost of the blockchain. Therefore, as long as blockchain technology is adopted, the consumer surplus can be improved. \subsection{Values of implementing BCT with government subsidies} After deriving the equilibrium decisions in the supply chains under Models G and Model BG, we now explore the values of blockchain technology with government subsidies. \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:value_bg} \begin{aligned} V_{x}^{BG}&=x^{BG}-x^{IG}\\ \end{aligned} \end{eqnarray} By comparing Model BG and Model IG, we report the results in \reftab{tab:value_decision_bg} and \reftab{tab:value_profit_bg} which leading to \refprop{prop:value_decision_bg} and \refprop{prop:value_profit_bg}. \begin{prop} \label{prop:value_decision_bg} Given $\kb$, $k$, $\theta$, $g$, $b$: $e^{BG}>e^{IG}$, $r^{BG}l^{IG}$, $p^{BG}>p^{IG}$. \end{prop} As shown, the results in \refprop{prop:value_decision_bg} are similar to \refprop{prop:value_decision_b}. It indicates that for given $\kb$, $k$, $\theta$, $g$, and $b$, under the government subsidies, the BCT helps to increase the probability of successful launch $e$, the retail price $p$, and decrease the premium rate $r$ under the government subsidies. Note that in the case of government subsidies, when the cost of vehicle is high, the effect of blockchain in increasing launch price is weakened compared to the absence of subsidies with a decrease of $\frac{\alpha g(k-\kb)}{(1-\alpha)^2}$ as shown in \reftab{tab:value_decision}. In addition, BCT has the same impact on each optimal decision, whether there is government subsidy or not. \begin{prop} \label{prop:value_profit_bg} Given $\kb$, $k$, $\theta$, $g$, $b$: \begin{enumerate}[(i)] \item If $\csb ~ \big( \begin{smallmatrix} < \\ =\\> \end{smallmatrix} \big)~ \min\{\frac{k\lambda ^2-\kb \psi^2}{128k\kb (1-\alpha)^2},\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\lambda-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\psi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}\}$, then we have: $V_{ SO}^{BG}~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~0$; \item When $\cv \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~\frac{k\lambda ^2-\kb \psi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\lambda-\psi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2} $ , for $\cv \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ 0$; when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, $V_{VM}^{BG} \equiv 0$ \item $V_{CS}^{BG}>0$ \item When $\cv \end{smallmatrix} \big) \frac{3k\lambda ^2-3\kb \psi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\lambda-\psi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b}{8} $, then we have $V_{SW}^{BG} ~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ 0$; when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, if $\csb ~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} < \\ =\\> \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ \frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\lambda-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\psi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b}{8}$, then we have $V_{SW}^{BG} ~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ 0$. \end{enumerate} \end{prop} The values of BCT under the case of government subsidies in \refprop{prop:value_profit_bg} are similar to the role of BCT without subsidies in \refprop{prop:value_profit_b}. Compared with Model IG, the BCT in Model BG helps to increase the profit of SO and the welfare of society when the cost of BCT is not high. For the VM, when $\cv(\csb+\cvb)_1$ and $(\csb)_4>(\csb)_3$). It implies that government subsidies are more likely to be preferred after adopting BCT. \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:value_decision_bg} Values of BCT with government subsidies on optimal decisions.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}} \toprule &{Situation}&{$V_{ e^*}^{BG}$}&{$V_{ r^*}^{BG}$}&{$V_{ l^*}^{BG}$}&{$V_{ p^*}^{BG}$} \\ \midrule Value & {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & $\frac{k[(1+b)^2+4\theta]-\kb(1+4\theta)}{16k\kb}>0$& $-\beta\frac{k[(1+b)^2+4\theta]-\kb(1+4\theta)}{16k\kb}<0$& $\frac{(1-\alpha)(b^2+2b)+8\alpha(1-g)(k-\kb)}{8(1-\alpha)^2}>0$& $\frac{b}{2}>0$\\ &{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }& $\frac{k\mu-\kb \omega}{k\kb(1-\alpha)}>0$& $-\beta$$\frac{k\mu-\kb \omega}{k\kb(1\alpha)}<0$& $\frac{2(\mu-\omega)+2\alpha(k-\kb)}{(1-\alpha)^2}>0$& $\frac{b}{2}>0$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \end{table*} \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:value_profit_bg} Values of BCT with government subsidies on members' payoffs.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}} \toprule &{Situation}&{$V_{ SO}^{BG}$}&{$V_{VM}^{BG}$}&{$V_{CS}^{BG}$}&{$V_{SW}^{BG}$} \\ \midrule Value & {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & $\frac{k\lambda ^2-\kb \psi^2}{128k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}-\csb$& $\frac{k\lambda ^2-\kb \psi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\lambda-\psi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}-\cvb$& $\frac{b^2+2b}{8}$& $\frac{3k\lambda ^2-3\kb \psi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\lambda-\psi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b}{8}-\csb-\cvb$\\ &{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }& $\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\lambda-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\psi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}-\csb$& $0$& $\frac{b^2+2b}{8}$& $\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\lambda-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\psi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b}{8}-\csb$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \end{table*} % %Furthermore, we compare the values of BCT under government subsidies with values of BCT without subsidies to explore the difference between adopting BCT impacted by the government subsidies. %For a clearer comparison, we built $\Delta V_i$ as follows and summarize the outcomes in \reftab{tab:value_decision} and \reftab{tab:value_profit}. % %\textcolor{red}{If we look at the impacts of having the penalty scheme under the case with technologies, we will find that the government’s use of penalty scheme will yield the following: (i) The cyber-security level is higher than the case without penalty scheme. (ii) Both the supplier and consumer are benefited from the scheme than without penalty scheme. (iii) The e-tailer’s profit is hurt than without penalty scheme.} % %In order to explore the impact of government subsidized with BCT, we define the following terms $\Delta V_{ SO}$, $\Delta V_{VM}$, $\Delta CS$, and $\Delta SW$, which represent the benefits that government subsidies and BCT bring to the SO, the VM, customers, and the society, respectively. % %\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:value_bg} % \begin{aligned} % \Delta V_{ SO}&=(\pbgs-\pgs)-(\pbs-\pis)\\ % \Delta V_{VM}&=(\pbgv-\pgv)-(\pbv-\piv)\\ % \Delta V_{CS}&=(CS^{BG}-CS^{IG})-(CS^{B}-CS^I)\\ % \Delta V_{SW}&=(SW^{BG}-SW^{IG})-(SW^{B}-SW^I)\\ % \end{aligned} %\end{eqnarray} % %\textcolor{red}{Furthermore, focusing on the thresholds (i.e., T for the case without technologies and TIT for the case with technologies) that determine whether implementing the government’s penalty scheme is beneficial to social welfare, we have the following findings: If F is relatively small and BCR > 1, then TIT is smaller than T. } \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:value_decision} The increases in the value of BCT on optimal decisions under government subsidies.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}} \toprule &{Situation}&{$\Delta V_{ e^*}^B$}&{$\Delta V_{ r^*}^B$}&{$\Delta V_{ l^*}^B$}&{$\Delta V_{ p^*}^B$} \\ \midrule $\Delta$Value & {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & $0$& $0$& $\frac{-\alpha g(k-\kb)}{(1-\alpha)^2}<0$& $0$\\ &{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }& $0$& $0$& $0$& $0$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \end{table*} \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:value_profit} The increases in the value of BCT on on members' payoffs under government subsidies.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}} \toprule &{Situation}&{$\Delta V_{ SO}^B$}&{$\Delta V_{VM}^B$}&{$\Delta V_{CS}^B$}&{$\Delta V_{SW}^B$} \\ \midrule $\Delta$Value & {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & $\frac{\alpha g [(1-\alpha ) b^2+2 (1-\alpha ) b+4 \alpha (2-g) (k-\kb)]}{8 (1-\alpha )^2}>0$& $\frac{\alpha g [(1-\alpha ) b^2+2 (1-\alpha ) b-4 \alpha (2+g) (k-\kb)]}{16 (1-\alpha )^2}>0$& $0$& $\frac{\alpha g [3(1-\alpha ) b^2+6(1-\alpha ) b+4 \alpha (2-3g) (k-\kb)]}{16 (1-\alpha )^2}>0$\\ &{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }& $\frac{2\alpha g[\alpha(k-\kb)-\omega+\mu]}{(-1 + \alpha)^2}>0$& $0$& $0$& $\frac{2\alpha g[\alpha(k-\kb)-\omega+\mu]}{(-1 + \alpha)^2}>0$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \end{table*} \section{Extended Models}\label{sec:extensions} \subsection{ Marginal cost of implementing BCT}\label{extend:model_c} In the models above, we assume the cost of BCT is a lump sum neglecting the marginal cost of BCT to acquire and store data, which may not be accurate in practice. Thus, we extend the blockchain models considering the marginal cost of implementing BCT denoted by $c$. We verify the robustness of our findings by exploring two cases that (i) blockchain-embedded satellite launch supply chain with insurance (Model B-c) (ii) blockchain-embedded satellite launch supply chain with government-subsidized insurance (Model BG-c). \subsubsection{Model B-c} According to the setting, the market demand of Model B-c can be written as follows: \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:bcd} % \left\{ \begin{aligned} D^{B-c} &= 1 \int_{p^{B-c}-b}^{1}{f\left( u \right) \mathrm{d} u}= 1-p^{B-c}+b \\ \end{aligned} % \right. \end{eqnarray} Therefore, the members' payoffs can be measured as follows: \begin{eqnarray} \begin{aligned} \pbcs &= e(p-c)D^{B-c} -[\alpha + e(1-\alpha) ]l - (r-g) (\cs + \alpha l) + (1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l)- \cs-\csb,\label{eq:bso:payoff}\\ \pi_I^{B-c}&= r (\cs + \alpha l)-(1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l),\\ \pbcv&=[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha) ]l - (1 - e) \theta - (\kb e^2 + \cv)-\cvb,\label{eq:bvm:payoff}\\ s.t.~\pbcv &\geq 0. \end{aligned} \end{eqnarray} Note, the only difference between Model B-c and Model B is that the BCT's marginal cost occurs to SO. We solve the derivation and summarize the outcomes in \reftab{tab:modelbc_decisions}. \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:modelbc_decisions} The equilibrium outcomes in Model B-c.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{c}@{}} \toprule & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ } \\ \midrule Effort of VM exerting $e^*$& $\frac{\eta -C}{16 (1-\alpha )\kb}$ & $\frac{\mu-\alpha \kb }{(1-\alpha)\kb}$ \\ Launch price $l^*$& $l^*=l_{S}=\frac{\eta-8\theta(1-\alpha)-C}{8(1-\alpha)^2}$& $ l^*=l_{VA}= \frac{2\mu-2\alpha \kb-(1-\alpha) \theta}{(1-\alpha)^2}$\\ Retail price $p^*$& $\frac{1+b+c}{2}$& $\frac{1+b+c}{2}$\\ Premium rate $r^*$& $\beta(1-\frac{\eta-C}{16(1-\alpha)\kb})$& $\beta\frac{\kb-\mu}{(1-\alpha)\kb}$\\ SO's profit $\pbcs$& $\frac{\eta^2-C(C-2\eta)}{128(1-\alpha)^2\kb}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha} -\cs-\csb$& $\frac{(\mu-\alpha \kb)(\eta+8\alpha \kb-8\mu-C)}{4(1-\alpha )^2\kb}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha}-\cs-\csb$\\ VM's profit $\pbcv$& $\frac{\eta^2+32\alpha \kb\eta-C(C-2\eta-32\alpha \kb)}{256(1-\alpha)^2\kb}-\frac{ \theta}{1-\alpha}-\cv-\cvb$& $0$\\ Consumer surplus $CS^{B-c}$& $\frac{(1+b-c)^2}{8}$& $\frac{(1+b-c)^2}{8}$&\\ Social welfare $SW^{B-c}$& $\frac{3\eta^2+32\alpha \kb\eta-C(3C-6\eta-32\alpha \kb)}{256(1-\alpha)^2\kb}- \theta-\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb+\frac{(1+b-c)^2}{8}$& $\frac{(\mu-\alpha \kb)(\phi+8\alpha \kb-8\mu-C)}{4(1-\alpha )^2\kb}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha}-\cs-\csb+\frac{(1+b-c)^2}{8}$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \begin{tablenotes} \item To avoid complicated writing, we define $\eta=(1-\alpha)(1+b)^2+4(1-\alpha)\theta-8\alpha \kb$, $\mu=\sqrt{(1-\alpha)^2\kb (\cv+\cvb)+\alpha ^2{\kb}^2-(1-\alpha)\kb \theta}$, $C=(1-\alpha)c(2+2b-c)$. \end{tablenotes} \end{table*} To explore the effect of blockchain marginal cost on the equilibrium outcomes, we compare Model B-c with Model B and obtain \refprop{prop:modelbc_vs_b}. \begin{prop} \label{prop:modelbc_vs_b} Under Model B-c, the satellite launch supply chain adopts the BCT with insurance considering the marginal cost of BCT. Compared with Model B, (i) when $\cvr^B$, $p^{B-c}>p^B$; (b) if $0< c< 1+b-\sqrt{\frac{(1-\alpha)(1+b)^2-2\eta}{1-\alpha}}$, $\pi_S^{B-c}>\pi_S^B$; otherwise, $\pi_S^{B-c} \leq \pi_S^B$; if $0\pi_V^B$; otherwise, $\pi_V^{B-c} \leq \pi_V^B$; $CS^{B-c}\pi_{SW}^B$; otherwise, $\pi_{SW}^{B-c} \leq \pi_{SW}^B$; (ii) when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, (a) $e^{B-c}=e^B$, $l^{B-c}=l^B$, $r^{B-c}=r^B$, $p^{B-c}>p^B$; (b) $\pi_S^{B-c}< \pi_S^B$; $\pi_V^{B-c} = \pi_V^B=0$; $CS^{B-c}e^I$, $r^{B-c}l^I$; otherwise, $l^{B-c}\leq l^I$; if $0p^I$, otherwise, $p^{B-c} \leq p^I$ (b) if $0 \pis$; otherwise, $\pbcs \leq \pis$; if $0\piv$; otherwise, $\pbcv \leq \piv$; if $0 CS^I$; otherwise, $CS^{B-c} \leq CS^I$; if $0SW^I$; otherwise, $SW^{B-c} \leq SW^I$. (ii) when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, (a) $e^{B-c}>e^I$, $l^{B-c}>l^I$, $r^{B-c}p^I$; otherwise, $p^{B-c} \leq p^I$; (b) if $\csb<\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}$, $\pbcs> \pis$; otherwise, $\pi_S^{B-c} \leq \pis$; $\pi_V^{B-c} = \piv=0$; if $0 CS^I$; otherwise, $CS^{B-c} \leq CS^I$; if $\csb<\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}$ and $0 \pi_{SW}^I$; otherwise, $\pi_{SW}^{B-c} \leq \pi_{SW}^I$. \end{prop} \refprop{prop:modelbc_vs_i} shows that when the BCT variation cost is within a certain interval, comparing Model B-c and Model I, the launch success probability increases, the launch price increases, the retail price increases, and the insurance rate decreases. This result is the same as the outcomes in \refprop{prop:value_decision_b} (comparing Model B with Model I). Moreover, by comparing the members' profits in Model B-c and Model I, we also find that when the marginal cost $c$ under a threshold and the cost of BCT is low, all the members will benefit from adopting BCT. Therefore, by comparing Model B-c and Model I in \refprop{prop:modelbc_vs_i}, our findings on the value of BCT are proved to be robust. \subsubsection{Model BG-c} Similar to Model BG, we build Model BG-c considering the marginal cost of BCT, which can be written as follows: \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:bgcd} % \left\{ \begin{aligned} D^{BG-c} &= 1 \int_{p^{BG-c}-b}^{1}{f\left( u \right) \mathrm{d} u}= 1-p^{BG-c}+b \\ \end{aligned} % \right. \end{eqnarray} Therefore, the members' payoffs can be measured as follows: \begin{eqnarray} \begin{aligned} \pbgcs &= e(p-c)D^{BG-c} -[\alpha + e(1-\alpha) ]l - (r-g) (\cs + \alpha l) + (1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l)- \cs-\csb,\label{eq:bso:payoff}\\ \pi_I^{BG-c}&= r (\cs + \alpha l)-(1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l),\\ \pbgcv&=[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha) ]l - (1 - e) \theta - (\kb e^2 + \cv)-\cvb,\label{eq:bvm:payoff}\\ s.t.~\pbgcv &\geq 0. \end{aligned} \end{eqnarray} Note, the only difference between Model BG-c and Model BG is that the BCT's marginal cost occurs to SO. We solve the derivation and summarize the outcomes in \reftab{tab:modelbgc_decisions}. \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:modelbgc_decisions} The equilibrium outcomes in Model BG-c.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{c}@{}} \toprule & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ } \\ \midrule Effort of VM exerting $e^*$& $\frac{\lambda -C}{16 (1-\alpha )\kb}$ & $\frac{\mu-\alpha \kb }{(1-\alpha)\kb}$ \\ Launch price $l^*$& $l^*=l_{S}=\frac{\lambda-8\theta(1-\alpha)-C}{8(1-\alpha)^2}$& $ l^*=l_{VA}= \frac{2\mu-2\alpha \kb-(1-\alpha) \theta}{(1-\alpha)^2}$\\ Retail price $p^*$& $\frac{1+b+c}{2}$& $\frac{1+b+c}{2}$\\ Premium rate $r^*$& $\beta(1-\frac{\lambda-C}{16(1-\alpha)\kb})$& $\beta\frac{\kb-\mu}{(1-\alpha)\kb}$\\ SO's profit $\pbcs$& $\frac{\lambda^2-C(C-2\lambda)}{128(1-\alpha)^2\kb}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha} -(1-g)\cs-\csb$& $\frac{(\mu-\alpha \kb)(\lambda+8\alpha \kb-8\mu-C)}{4(1-\alpha )^2\kb}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha}-(1-g)\cs-\csb$\\ VM's profit $\pbcv$& $\frac{\lambda^2+32\alpha \kb\lambda-C(C-2\lambda-32\alpha \kb)}{256(1-\alpha)^2\kb}-\frac{ \theta}{1-\alpha}-\cv-\cvb$& $0$\\ Consumer surplus $CS^{B-c}$& $\frac{(1+b-c)^2}{8}$& $\frac{(1+b-c)^2}{8}$&\\ Social welfare $SW^{B-c}$& $\frac{3\lambda^2+32\alpha \kb\lambda-C(3C-6\lambda-32\alpha \kb)}{256(1-\alpha)^2\kb}- \frac{\theta[1-(1-g)\alpha]}{1-\alpha}-(1-g)\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb+\frac{(1+b-c)^2}{8}$& $\frac{(\mu-\alpha \kb)(\phi+8\alpha \kb-8\mu-C)}{4(1-\alpha )^2\kb}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{1-\alpha}-(1-g)\cs-\csb+\frac{(1+b-c)^2}{8}$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \begin{tablenotes} \item To avoid complicated writing, we define $\lambda=(1-\alpha)(1+b)^2+4(1-\alpha)\theta-8\alpha \kb$, $\mu=\sqrt{(1-\alpha)^2\kb (\cv+\cvb)+\alpha ^2{\kb}^2-(1-\alpha)\kb \theta}$, $C=(1-\alpha)c(2+2b-c)$. \end{tablenotes} \end{table*} To explore the effect of blockchain marginal cost on the equilibrium outcomes under government subsidies, we compare model BG-c with Model BG and obtain \refprop{prop:modelbgc_vs_bg}. \begin{prop} \label{prop:modelbgc_vs_bg} Under Model BG-c, the satellite launch supply chain adopts the BCT with government-subsidies insurance considering the marginal cost of BCT. Compared with Model BG, (i) when $\cvr^{BG}$, $p^{BG-c}>p^{BG}$; (b) if $0< c< 1+b-\sqrt{\frac{(1-\alpha)(1+b)^2-2\lambda}{1-\alpha}}$, $\pbgcs>\pbgs$; otherwise, $\pbgcs \leq \pbgs $; if $0\pbgv$; otherwise, $\pbgcv \leq \pbgv$; $CS^{BG-c}\pi_{SW}^{BG}$; otherwise, $\pi_{SW}^{BG-c} \leq \pi_{SW}^{BG}$; (ii) when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, (a) $e^{BG-c}=e^{BG}$, $l^{BG-c}=l^{BG}$, $r^{BG-c}=r^{BG}$, $p^{BG-c}>p^{BG}$; (b) $\pi_S^{BG-c}< \pi_S^{BG}$; $\pi_V^{BG-c} = \pi_V^{BG}=0$; $CS^{BG-c}e^{IG}$, $r^{BG-c}l^{IG}$; otherwise, $l^{BG-c}\leq l^{IG}$; if $0p^{IG}$, otherwise, $p^{BG-c} \leq p^{IG}$ (b) if $0 \pgs$; otherwise, $\pbgcs \leq \pgs$; if $0\pgv$; otherwise, $\pbgcv \leq \pgv$; if $0 CS^{IG}$; otherwise, $CS^{BG-c} \leq CS^{IG}$; if $0SW^{IG}$; otherwise, $SW^{BG-c} \leq SW^{IG}$. (ii) when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, (a) $e^{BG-c}>e^{IG}$, $l^{BG-c}>l^{IG}$, $r^{BG-c}p^{IG}$; otherwise, $p^{BG-c} \leq p^{IG}$; (b) if $\csb<\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\lambda-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\psi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}$, $\pbgcs> \pgs$; otherwise, $\pbgcs \leq \pgs$; $\pi_V^{BG-c} = \pgv=0$; if $0 CS^{IG}$; otherwise, $CS^{BG-c} \leq CS^{IG}$; if $\csb<\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}$ and $0 \pi_{SW}^{IG}$; otherwise, $\pi_{SW}^{BG-c} \leq \pi_{SW}^{IG}$. \end{prop} The results in \refprop{prop:modelbgc_vs_g} are similar to \refprop{prop:modelbc_vs_i} that comparing Model BG-c and Model G,the launch success probability increases, the launch price increases, the retail price increases, and the insurance rate decreases with the BCT variation cost in a certain interval. This result is the same as the outcomes in \refprop{prop:value_decision_bg} (comparing Model BG with Model IG). Besides, by comparing members' profits in Model BG-c and Model IG, we also find that when the marginal cost $c$ under a threshold and the cost of BCT is low, all the members will benefit from adopting BCT under government subsidies. Therefore, by comparing Model BG-c and Model IG, our findings in \refprop{prop:value_decision_bg} and \refprop{prop:value_profit_bg} about the value of BCT with the government subsidy are proved to be robust. \subsection{Alliance} Inspired by alliances in the real-world alliances, such as U.S. Space Enterprise Consortium and China Commercial Space Alliance, we extend the models to explore if an alliance strategy is a better to improve the effective of satellite launch supply chain in this section. On the basis of the main cases, we build three models: (i) the VM and SO form an alliance with launch insurance (Model IA); (ii) the VM and SO form an alliance with launch insurance under government subsidies(Model GA); (iii) the VM and SO form an alliance with blockchain-embedded launch insurance (Model BA); (iv) the VM and SO form an alliance with blockchain-embedded launch insurance under government subsidies (Model BGA). In the above models, the VM and the SO attempt to maximize their respective benefits, VM by deciding the effort to be paid, and SO by determining the launch service price and retail price. However, in the alliance strategy, VM and SO will act as a whole alliance to decide the efforts exert and the retail price. Thus the market demand and payoff functions of Model IA can be written as follows: \begin{eqnarray} % \left\{ \begin{aligned} D^{IA} &= 1 \int_{p^{IA}}^{1}{f\left( u \right) \mathrm{d} u}= 1-p^{IA} \\ \end{aligned} % \right. \end{eqnarray} \begin{eqnarray} \begin{aligned} \pia&= epD^{IA} -(1 - e) \theta - r \cs + (1-e)\beta \cs-\cs-\cv,\\ \pi_I^{IA}&= r \cs -(1-e)\beta \cs.\\ \end{aligned} \end{eqnarray} The functions of Model GA, Model BA, and model BGA are similar to Model IA which we omit here. By inverse solving, we obtain the equilibrium outcomes which are summarized in \reftab{tab:modelia_modelga_decisions} and \reftab{tab:modelba_modelbga_decisions} \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:modelia_modelga_decisions} The equilibrium outcomes in Model IA and Model GA.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{c}@{}} \toprule & \multicolumn{1}{c}{Model IA } & \multicolumn{1}{c}{Model GA } \\ % \multicolumn{1}{c}{Model BA } &\multicolumn{1}{c}{Model BGA } \\ \midrule Effort of SC exerting $e^*$& $\frac{1+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8k}$ & $\frac{1+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8k}$ \\ % $\frac{(1+b)^2+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8\kb}$& % $\frac{(1+b)^2+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8\kb}$ \\ Retail price $p^*$& $\frac{1}{2}$& $\frac{1}{2}$\\ % $\frac{1}{2}$\\ Premium rate $r^*$& $\beta(1-\frac{1+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8k})$& $\beta(1-\frac{1+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8k})$\\ % $\beta(1-\frac{(1+b)^2+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8\kb})$ \\ SC's profit $\pi_{SC}$& $\frac{(1+4\theta)^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64k}-\theta-\cs-\cv$& $\frac{(1+4\theta)^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64k}-\theta-(1-g)\cs-\cv$\\ % $\frac{[(1+b)^2+4\theta]^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64k}-\theta-\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb$\\ Consumer surplus $CS$& $\frac{1}{8}$& $\frac{1}{8}$\\ % $\frac{1}{8}$\\ Social welfare $SW$& $\frac{(1+4\theta)^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64k}-\theta-\cs-\cv+\frac{1}{8}$& $\frac{(1+4\theta)^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64k}-\theta-(1-g)\cs-\cv+\frac{1}{8}$\\ % $\frac{[(1+b)^2+4\theta]^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64k}-\theta-\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb+\frac{1}{8}$\\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \end{table*} \begin{table*}[htbp] \scriptsize % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} \caption{\label{tab:modelba_modelbga_decisions} The equilibrium outcomes in Model BA and Model BGA.} \centering \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{c}@{}} \toprule & \multicolumn{1}{c}{Model BA } &\multicolumn{1}{c}{Model BGA } \\ \midrule Effort of SC exerting $e^*$& $\frac{(1+b)^2+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8\kb}$& $\frac{(1+b)^2+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8\kb}$ \\ Retail price $p^*$& $\frac{1+b}{2}$& $\frac{1+b}{2}$\\ Premium rate $r^*$& $\beta(1-\frac{(1+b)^2+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8\kb})$& $\beta(1-\frac{(1+b)^2+4\theta-4\beta \cs}{8\kb})$ \\ SC's profit $\pi_{SC}$& $\frac{[(1+b)^2+4\theta]^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64\kb}-\theta-\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb$& $\frac{[(1+b)^2+4\theta]^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64\kb}-\theta-(1-g)\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb$\\ Consumer surplus $CS$& $\frac{(1+b)^2}{8}$& $\frac{(1+b)^2}{8}$\\ Social welfare $SW$& $\frac{[(1+b)^2+4\theta]^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64\kb}-\theta-\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb+\frac{(1+b)^2}{8}$& $\frac{[(1+b)^2+4\theta]^2-(4\beta \cs)^2}{64\kb}-\theta-(1-g)\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb+\frac{(1+b)^2}{8}$ \\ \bottomrule \end{tabular} \end{table*} The outcomes above imply a difference that the optimal decisions are effected by the insurance market instead of the prepay rule. That means, as the VM and SO form an alliance, the motivation of VM to improve the successful launch probability changes from the prepay ratio ($\alpha$) to the insurance claim ($\beta \cs$). Thus, the less insurance covers, the more effort VM exerts. By comparing Model IA and Model I, model GA and Model IG, Model BA and Model B, Model BGA and Model BG, we get \refprop{prop:modela_vs_model}. \begin{prop}\label{prop:modela_vs_model} When the VM and the SO form an alliance, (i) comparing Model IA and Model I, if $\beta\cs<\frac{(1-\alpha)(1+4\theta)+8\alpha k }{ 8(1-\alpha)}$, then $e^{IA}>e^I$ and $\swia>SW^{I}$; (ii) comparing Model GA and Model G, if $\beta\cs<\frac{(1-\alpha)(1+4\theta)+8\alpha k(1-g)}{ 8(1-\alpha)}$, then $e^{GA}>e^{IG}$; if $ (\beta\cs)^2<\frac{[(1-\alpha)(1+4\theta)+8\alpha k(1-g)]^2+32\alpha kg[(4\theta-1)(1-\alpha)+8\alpha k(1-g)]}{[8(1-\alpha)]^2} $, then $\swga>SW^{IG}$; (iii) comparing Model BA and Model B, if $ \beta\cs<\frac{(1-\alpha)[(1+b)^2+4\theta]+8\alpha \kb }{8(1-\alpha)}$, $e^{BA}>e^B$ and $\swba > SW^{B}$; (iv) comparing Model BGA and Model BG, if $\beta\cs<\frac{(1-\alpha))[(1+b)^2+4\theta]+8\alpha \kb(1-g)}{8(1-\alpha)} $, $e^{BGA}>e^{BG}$; if $ (\beta\cs)^2<\frac{\{(1-\alpha)[(1+b)^2+4\theta]+8\alpha \kb(1-g)\}^2+32\alpha \kb g\{[4\theta-(1+b)^2](1-\alpha)+8\alpha \kb(1-g)\} }{[8(1-\alpha)]^2}$, $\swbga>SW^{BG}$. \end{prop} \refprop{prop:modela_vs_model} gives the specific insurance claim thresholds for the adoption of the alliance strategy under four scenarios. Note that the retail price paid by the consumer and the consumer surplus remain the same, so the increased social welfare mainly comes from the increase in supply chain profits. Therefore, when the insurance market is soft, it would be a wise idea to pursue an alliance strategy in the satellite launch supply chain. It will contribute to an increase in the probability of successful launches as well as to the improvement of social welfare. \section{Conclusions}\label{sec:conclusions} \subsection{Remarkble findings} Nowadays, with the prosperity of commercial launches, more and more research is being conducted in the operation management of space. Motivated by the real-world government-subsidized launch insurance project, we explored the operations of the satellite launch supply chain with government-subsidized insurance. Firstly, we established the traditional insurance model (Model I) and the government-subsidized insurance model (Model IG). By deriving analytical results, we demonstrate the optimal decisions for each participant. We have further uncovered the effect of the subsidies on different variables. Finally, we built value models to investigate the benefit of subsidies, especially revealing the conditions under which one model outperforms the other. However, we find that if only the government provides subsidies, the customers cannot benefit. So we investigate the blockchain applications in the space launch supply chain by building a blockchain-embedded insurance model (Model B), which has also been implemented in the real world. Besides, considering the high blockchain costs, we explored the scenario of adopting blockchain under government subsidies (Model BG). At last, in order to measure the value of blockchain under different scenarios, we compare Model B with Model I and Model BG with Model IG. And we analyzed the change of blockchain impact under the government subsidy scenario. As a concluding remark, we highlight the answers as follows: \begin{enumerate} [(1)] \item Government subsidized launch insurance can achieve win-win in satellite launch supply chain and improve the social welfare. However, it is not always preferred to implement the government subsidy in all cases. When the government provides subsidies, it is necessary to screen satellite vendors, and only by subsidizing satellite launch activities with inexpensive vehicles can it effectively promote the development of the launch market. Otherwise, subsidies can only increase the profit of satellite operators but can not promote the launch success rate, which is not conducive to the optimal allocation of government funds. \item The government subsidies have helped to establish positive feedback for the satellite launch market; that is, the satellite vendor is more willing to pay high launch price, so that the vehicle manufacturer is motivated to increase the probability of successful launches. \item Once the government subsidy project is launched, the satellite operator will always get more from it than before. But for the vehicle manufacturer, only when the cost of vehicle is relatively low, his income will increase compared to before; otherwise, he cannot benefit from the subsidy program. For consumers, there is no change in consumer surplus. Therefore, the overall social welfare as the sum of the profit of the various subjects will increase. \item In the blockchain-embedded model, the values that blockchain bring to the optimal decisions are similar to the government subsidy brings. However, there is one difference to claim that the retail price has been increased and the market demand also increases. \item Moreover, for the satellite, she will always benefit from the adoption of blockchain if its cost is relatively low. \item However, the profitable condition for the vehicle to decide whether use the blockchain is not only the cost of blockchain is expensive but also the cost of vehicle manufacturing is low. \item Significantly, the use of the blockchain launch platform will make the consumer surplus increase no matter in which situation. \item Interestingly, the adoption of blockchain can increase the benefits of government subsidies. Besides, when the supply chain obtains the government subsidies, both the satellite operator and the vehicle manufacture can enhance the affordability of blockchain costs. \end{enumerate} \subsection{Managerial implications} Analyzing the derived findings, we further propose the following managerial implications, which help form action plans for satellite operators, vehicle manufacturers, and the government.\par Satellite operator: It is the most effective to improve profit by applying for government insurance subsidies. Moreover, the adoption of the blockchain-embedded launch platform will also enhance the profit when the cost of blockchain is low.\par Vehicle manufacturer: Only when vehicle costs are low can manufacturers indirectly enjoy the benefits of government subsidies. Otherwise, the manufacturer will be nonprofitable. However, it is worth noting that adopting blockchain technology to provide launch services is always beneficial for vehicle manufacturers, as it can increase the probability of a successful launch. Besides, when the blockchain and vehicle manufacturing costs are low, adopting blockchain technology is the best strategy for the manufacturer, which will improve his profitability.\par Government: Intuitively, government provision of insurance subsidies can improve social welfare. However, the excellent way to optimally allocate the limited subsidy funds is to disburse the subsidies to satellite operators who choose cost-effective vehicles. This is because it is in this condition that the probability of a successful launch is increased, and a virtuous closed-loop commercial satellite launch market is promoted. Finally, this results in a win-win situation in the supply chain. However, it is worth noting that when the government provides subsidies to blockchain technology embedded launch activities, it will maximize the funds' effectiveness, achieving all-win among the satellite operator, the vehicle manufacturer, and customers. \subsection{ Future research} For the future studies, we suggest several probable future directions. First, the risk attitude of different participants can be taken into account which will effect the optimal decisions. Second, the JIT operation management with the supported of blockchain in launch supply chain can be promising directions for future research. Last but not least, multi-tier supply chain or supply chain network will be interesting to investigate, which involve more members such as the rideshare broker in piggyback launch and rideshare or cluster launch \citep{Barschke2020}. % A table containing numbers is more complex. \reftab{tab:result} shows how to add a wide table with different alignments. It is suggested that use an Excel plugin ``Excel2LaTeX.xla'' to create a data table. % \begin{table*}[htbp] % \scriptsize %% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown. % \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}} % \caption{\label{tab:result} Experimental results for the data sets \textit{Random} and \textit{Circles}.} % \centering % \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3} % \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{2pt}}l*{14}{r}@{}} % \toprule % \multirow{2}*{Index} % & \multicolumn{7}{c}{Random} % & \multicolumn{7}{c}{Circles}\\ % \cline{2-8}\cline{9-15} % & \multicolumn{1}{c}{20} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{60} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{100} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{200} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{300} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{400} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{500} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{20} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{60} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{100} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{200} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{300} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{400} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{500}\\ % \midrule % $z_1$ & 0.85 & 0.6 & 0.53 & 0.44 & 0.41 & 0.42 & 0.41 & 0.6 & 0.45 & 0.43 & 0.41 & 0.39 & 0.4 & 0.38\\ % $z_2$ & 0.85 & 0.46 & 0.51 & 0.4 & 0.39 & 0.4 & 0.37 & 0.45 & 0.42 & 0.38 & 0.38 & 0.37 & 0.37 & 0.37\\ % \bottomrule % \end{tabular} % \end{table*} % % \section{Math} % In-text equations like $a_{ij,t} \sim N(75, 25^2)$. For multiple equations, use \textit{eqnarray} and \& to align. % \begin{equation}\label{equ:utility} % U_{ij,t} = \left(\frac{W^{min}_{i,t}}{W_{ij,t}} \right)^{1-\beta}\cdot \left( \frac{Q_{j,t}}{Q^{max}_{t}} \right) ^{\beta}, % \end{equation} % where % \begin{eqnarray} % \label{equ:maxtau} W^{\min}_{i,t}&=&\min \{W_{ij,t}\}^N_{j=1}, \\ % \label{equ:minfq} Q^{\max}_{t}&=&\max \{Q_{j,t}\}^N_{j=1}. % \end{eqnarray}\par % \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:B5} % \left\{ % \begin{aligned} % &\frac{\partial \pi_1}{\partial p_1} % = \dfrac{Qe^{b-ap_1}}{\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}} % + \dfrac{a(c_1-p_1)Qe^{b-ap_1}}{\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}} % - \dfrac{a(c_1-p_1)Qe^{2(b-ap_1)}}{\big(\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}\big)^2} = 0,\\ % &\dots,\\ % &\frac{\partial \pi_n}{\partial p_n} % = \dfrac{Qe^{b-ap_n}}{\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}} % + \dfrac{a(c_n-p_n)Qe^{b-ap_n}}{\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}} % - \dfrac{a(c_n-p_n)Qe^{2(b-ap_n)}}{\big(\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}\big)^2} = 0. % \end{aligned} % \right. % \end{eqnarray} % \begin{equation}\label{equ:if} % f(x)= % \begin{cases} % \frac{x^2-x}{x},& \text{if } x\geq 1\\ % 0, & \text{otherwise} % \end{cases} % \end{equation} % % \section{Citation} % Use \textbackslash{citet} when the authors are the subject of a sentence; otherwise use \textbackslash{citep}. For example, \citet{1929-Hotelling-p41-57} has spurred voluminous subsequent research on this topic... The term O2O originally means that the customer enjoys the product or service offline through buying online \citep{2010-Rampell-p-}. By means of agent-based modelling (ABM), the CAS theory can be applied to study various complex systems such as ecosystems, supply networks, financial markets, economies, and social systems \citep[see, e.g., ][]{2009-Farmer-p685-686, 2016-Chandrasekaran-p390-416}.\par % % % \section{Conclusion}\label{sec:conclusion} % The conclusion goes here.\par % % % \section*{Acknowledgement} % Dong was supported in part by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71573244, 71532013, 71202115 and 71403260). The authors acknowledge Mr. XXX for providing useful data and suggestions. The authors greatly appreciate the editor and anonymous referees for their comments, which helped to improve this paper. % % \appendix % \section{Pseudo Codes}\label{sec:apd:code} % \subsection{The procedure} % Algorithm \refalg{alg:CIPS} shows a piece of pseudo code.\par % \begin{figure}%[!t] % % \removelatexerror % \begin{algorithm}[H] % \caption{The CIPS generation procedure}\label{alg:CIPS} % \KwData{A set $Y$ containing $n$ demand points with ($x$, $y$) coordinates and coverage radius $R$.} % \KwResult{A set $C$ consisting of intersection points and demand points with their coordinates.} % % initialize population $P = \left \{ X_{1}, ... , X_{N} \right \} $\; % Create a temporary set copied from $Y$\; % \For( \emph{loop $Y$}){$i$ in range($n$)} % { % \For( \emph{loop $Y$}){$j$ in range($n$)} % { % $d_{i,j} =$ distance between $Y_i$ and $Y_j$\; % \If{$0 < d_{i,j}\leq2R$ } % { % Calculate the coordinates of intersection points\; % Add generated IPs to the temporary set\; % } % } % } % Return the temporary set as $C$\; % \end{algorithm} % \end{figure} % % \newpage %% \section*{References} \bibliographystyle{model5-names-with-volume-number} % \bibliographystyle{IEEEtran} %\bibliographystyle{ACM-Reference-Format} \bibliography{SAVM} \end{document}