IGB/manuscript.tex

1456 lines
91 KiB
TeX
Raw Normal View History

2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
\documentclass[authoryear,times,review,12pt,3p]{elsarticle}
%special commands
\newcommand{\ds}{\displaystyle}
\newtheorem{lem}{Lemma}[section]
\newtheorem{prop}{Proposition}[section]
% Special Characters
%model I
\newcommand{\E}{\mathbb{E}}
\newcommand{\cv}{c_{V}}
\newcommand{\cs}{c_{S}}
\newcommand{\piv}{\pi_{V}^I}
\newcommand{\pis}{\pi_{S}^I}
%model IG
\newcommand{\pgv}{\pi_{V}^{IG}}
\newcommand{\pgs}{\pi_{S}^{IG}}
%model B
\newcommand{\cvb}{c_{VB}}
\newcommand{\csb}{c_{SB}}
\newcommand{\pbs}{\pi_{S}^B}
\newcommand{\pbv}{\pi_{V}^B}
\newcommand{\eb}{e^B}
\newcommand{\rb}{r^B}
\newcommand{\pb}{p^B}
\newcommand{\kb}{k^{B}}
\newcommand{\pbb}{p^{B*}}
%Model BG
\newcommand{\pbgs}{\pi_{S}^{BG}}
\newcommand{\pbgv}{\pi_{V}^{BG}}
\newcommand{\rv}{r_{V}}
\newcommand{\rvb}{r_{V}^B}
\newcommand{\vso}{V_{SO}}
\newcommand{\vvm}{V_{VM}}
%refer to website
\usepackage{url}
% enable math symbols
\usepackage[cmex10]{amsmath}
\usepackage{mdwmath}
\usepackage{amssymb}
% mdwtab can be used to align equations and tables
\usepackage{array}
\usepackage{mdwtab}
\usepackage{graphicx}
% powful tools for table
\usepackage{booktabs}
\usepackage{tabularx}
\usepackage{multirow}
\usepackage{rotating}
\usepackage[flushleft]{threeparttable}
% change the position of figures or tables
\usepackage{float}
\usepackage{subcaption}
% only used in revisions
\usepackage{changes}
% self-defined commands or simply
\newcommand{\reffig}[1]{Figure~\ref{#1}}
\newcommand{\reftab}[1]{Table~\ref{#1}}
\newcommand{\refequ}[1]{Equation~(\ref{#1})}
\newcommand{\refcstr}[1]{Constraint~\ref{#1}}
\newcommand{\refsec}[1]{Section~\ref{#1}}
\newcommand{\refalg}[1]{Algorithm~\ref{#1}}
\newcommand{\reflem}[1]{Lemma~\ref{#1}}
\newcommand{\refprop}[1]{Proposition~\ref{#1}}
% change the journal name before submitting
\journal{Journal of XYZ}
\begin{document}
\begin{frontmatter}
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
\title{ Coordination of insured satellite launch supply chain: government subsidy or blockchain adoption?}
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
\author[]{xxx}\ead{xxx@ucas.ac.cn}
\author[SEMUCAS,BDCAS]{xxxx}\ead{xxx@ucas.ac.cn}
\author[SEMUCAS,BDCAS]{xxx\corref{Cor}}\ead{CorrespondingAuthor@ucas.ac.cn}
\address[SDCUCAS]{Sino-Danish College, University of Chinese Academy of Sciences, No.3(A) Zhongguancun South Yitiao Road, Beijing 100190, China}
\address[SEMUCAS]{School of Economics and Management, University of Chinese Academy of Sciences, 80 Zhongguancun East Road, Beijing 100190, China}
\address[BDCAS]{Key Laboratory of Big Data Mining and Knowledge Management, Chinese Academy of Sciences, 80 Zhongguancun East Road, Beijing 100190, China.}
\cortext[Cor]{Corresponding author. Tel.: +86 10 88250000; fax: +86 10 88250000.}
\begin{abstract}
% problem definition: what is the business problem
The commercial launch industry is booming but abounds enormous-loss risks, which is similar to the disruption risk in the supply chain.
Traditionally, launch insurance is the commonly used financial tool to hedge such risks.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
However, the insurance, as the third highest cost after the satellite' cost and the launch service cost, makes satellite operators prohibitive.
Moreover, in order to alleviate the financial pressure on private satellite operators, some governments have implemented the measures for subsidizing the insurance fee for commercial space launches aiming to promote the development of the commercial space industry.
Besides, with the development of blockchain technology, it also is adopted to decrease launch risks and expand market from a technical perspective.
However, a tricky question is how to make a cost-effective decision for the satellite operator between government-subsidy insurance and blockchain-embed insurance.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
% Academic /Practice relevance: what have others done
In this paper, we apply a game-theoretic approach to study the fintech launch contract supported by government subsidy or blockchain for solving the trade-off between high risk and high cost.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
More precisely, we consider a Stackelberg strategy in a space launch supply chain and build math models to examine the cases with launch insurance (Model I), with government-subsidy (Model IG) and with blockchain-embedded (Model IB).
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
From a theoretical perspective, we investigate the optimal launch price and the optimal effort (for improving launch success probability) expressions.
We find that if the government wants to form a virtuous circle and optimize the allocation of funds, it should screen when subsidizing satellite companies, rather than unconditional subsidies.
In addition, we also find that the subsidy do not benefit consumers, but blockchain can.
Once the blockchain technology is adopted, contract prices go up, VM exerts more effort, and the premium rate always is lower as the launch missions become more efficient and believable.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
Moreover, when the satellite operator choose an inexpensive vehicle for launch, the cost-advantage BEL platform is beneficial to all participants.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
Finally, coupling with these findings, we further discuss the managerial implications for the commercial space launch market.
\end{abstract}
\begin{keyword}
Satellite launch \sep insurance\sep government subsidy \sep blockchain \sep commercial launch supply chain
\end{keyword}
% \section{Highlights}
% (1) This paper investigates the implement of blockchain technologies in the commercial launch industry, which can effectively improve the efficient of data flow.\par
% (2)Two mathematical models have been built: insurance model and blockchain-embedded model. \par
% (3) Uncover the threshold of using blockchain for each participant.\par
% (4) Reveal the adoption of blockchain can improve supply chain members to achieve a win-win situation. \par
\end{frontmatter}
% usually, add a new page before introduction
\newpage
\section{Introduction}\label{sec:introduction}
\subsection{Background}
% 商业卫星行业的兴起。商业航空越来越重要。
% With the prosperity of commercial space, more and more
% The global space economy is growing. Governments around the world are realising the potential the space industry could be bringing into their respective economies. An exceptional amount of capital is being invested both by governments and the private sector.\par
% With commercial passenger sub-orbital launches imminent, human spaceflight will become more commonplace. The “NewSpace” arena also has projects ranging from active debris removal and artificial shooting stars missions to lunar gateway and space hotel concepts as well as human lunar and Mars missions.\par
% Space insurance has always been an enabler of new projects, providing both hull and liability coverages. Despite the market and technical challenges, space insurers will continue to support the industry going forward.\par
Due to Earths insatiable need for information and communication, the artificial satellite industry is booming.
The ability of satellites to collect signals and data extensively, even from places hard to reach, allows for a variety of functions such as providing satellite telecommunication, satisfying weather and climate monitoring, supporting satellite television (BskyB, Direct TV, SkyTV and Dish), meeting Global Positioning System (GPS) needs, and serving for military and scientific.
Since the 1980s, with the privatization of telecommunication organizations as well as the development of space laws and regulatory regimes, commercial space has begun to sprout \citep{OECD2014}.
Furthermore, SpaceX Falcon 9 delivering the SES-8 satellite into orbit marks on Dec.3th, 2013, marks the rise of the private space launch market \citep{spacex}.
Space is no longer confined to government and military agencies like NASA and its contractors but expanding rapidly via private commercial companies like SpaceX, Blue Origin, Cloud Constellation Corporation, and more.
According to \cite{TheSpaceReport2021}, the space economy grew $176\%$ during the last 15 years, reaching $447$ billion dollars in 2020. It is worth noting that $80\%$ of the total income is contributed by the commercial space. In addition, there are more than 1,100 SmallSats launched in 2020, which is twice in average size over the same period.
Thus the space launch market gradually plays a pivotal part in modern societies and economic growth.
In parallel, the vigorous development of the space economy also points that the needs of operation management implanting in the space launch market are increasing \citep{Kucukcay}.
%商业航天面临的问题
While the successful SpaceX mission has created new enthusiasm for commercial satellite launching, there are still many risks that should not be ignored in satellite launch services, such as the responsibility of the vehicle, the indicators of the satellite, the condition of the launch activity so on.
In addition, many private investors are hesitant about investing in space businesses because of the costly infrastructure and extended timelines.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
From the perspective of private companies, once the launch fails, the loss for both satellite operator and launch servicer is enormous. While governmental and military satellites are usually self-insured, commercial satellite operators often require insurance to be in place.\par
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
% 解决商业航天风险的一个途径是购买航天保险。
In order to hedge launch risks, space insurance emerged. Insurance companies like Global Aerospace have been providing insurance for space initiatives since the first commercial satellites and launch vehicles required financial support to cover their risk.
New concepts and technologies such as prominent constellations of satellites have distinctive risk profiles requiring unique coverages.
According to the satellite launch project process, space insurance is roughly divided into four types of coverage which reflect the various phases of most satellite projects - pre-launch insurance \footnote{ Pre-launch insurance covers damage to a satellite or launch vehicle during the construction, transportation, and processing phases prior to launch.},
launch insurance \footnote{ Launch insurance covers losses of a satellite occurring during the launch phase of a project. It insures against complete launch failures as well as the failure of a launch vehicle to place a satellite in the proper orbit.},
in-orbit insurance \footnote{In-orbit policies insure satellites for in-orbit technical problems and damages once a satellite has been placed by a launch vehicle in its proper orbit.},
and launch plus life insurance \footnote{Third-party liability and government property insurances protect launch service providers and their customers in the event of public injury or government property damage, respectively, caused by launch or mission failure.}.
The launch insurance is usually the most widely focused \citep{Suchodolski2018} because the launch is the riskiest part of any space activity, and the damage is often catastrophic. \citep{Gould2000, Kunstadter2020}. \par
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
Concerning about the high premium, some governments have introduced policies to subsidize the commercial industry.
For example, Beijing Bureau of Economy and Information Technology has implemented an subsidy about commercial space launch insurance to support commercial space enterprises to engage in the production and manufacture of vehicles and satellites in Beijing, and encourage commercial space enterprises to establish headquarters, sales and operation in Beijing.
In addition, Russian and Japan also provide government indemnification for the loss of satellite launching activity.
Besides, the UK government invested in launch sites to provide new satellite launch services mentioned in its industrial strategy white paper.
The Unites States not only provided subsidy for launch liability insurance but also awarded the commercial companies directly.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
% 除了在金融方面补偿风险外,还可以通过提升技术的方式降低发射失败率。
In addition to compensating for risk financially, reducing the launch failure rate on the technical side is also an available way for commercial space companies.
While commercialized space projects have braved all the challenges, they are still involved in conventional economic models that may hamper their growth and success. Luckily, blockchain technology supports building smart contracts and tracking data, considered a disruptive technology that facilitates data flow.
In the real world, companies are emerging to implementing blockchain technology specifically for space launches, such as SpaceChain, IBM and Cloud Constellation Corporation.
The blockchain is used to deal with the above complexities such as contracts, order tracking, parts assembly, shipments, design and test documents, test results data, near real-time data, workflows for approvals, auditing, launch, and control, which make the project more visible, responsive and mitigate costly interruptions during the launch, in other words, it increases the probability of successful launch \citep{Zheng2021}.
Here are the main features in details of blockchain about supporting space launch:\par
%
% \begin{table}[htbp]
% \scriptsize
% \caption{\label{tab:blockchain features} Features of blockchain about supporting space launch}
% \centering
% \begin{threeparttable}
% \begin{tabular}{c p{0.6\columnwidth}} % lcr: left, center, right
% \toprule
% Features & Details\\
% \midrule
% Responsiveness & It enable intelligent, end-to-end supply chain visibility and transparency which allows participants owning permission to check and record data.\\
(1) Reliability: The verified data on the blockchain launch platform is reliable, which cannot be changed based on decentralizing electronic record-keeping. \par
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
(2) Efficiency: Blockchain supports the smart contract to build an efficient network between the participants who get a node to share, add and update information.\
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
% \bottomrule
% \end{tabular}
% \end{threeparttable}
% \end{table}
%
%what is the trade off (the good thing and the bad thing) and what we do
Despite the ideas given above being excellent, both space insurance and blockchain technology are high-cost, which make lots of private space companies hesitate to adopt them.
Considering the trade-off between handling risk and considerable cost, we examine the contract price problem.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
From the perspective of operation management, we refer to the participants as supply chain members and simplify the question as a two-echelon supply chain consisting of a satellite operator and vehicle manufacturer who provide the launch service.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
We examine how the insurance contract and blockchain technology to help improve the supply chain value and how it affects the contract price in the supply chain.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
We consider two modes: 1) the satellite operator contract with the vehicle manufacturer under insurance; 2) the satellite operator contracts with the vehicle manufacturer under blockchain-embedded insurance.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
\subsection{Research questions and key findings}
Motivated by the application of fintech and the importance of space launching operation management in the real world, we theoretically study the research questions listed below:\par
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
RQ1. How to analytically build the mathematical models under traditional launch insurance, government-subsidy insurance, and blockchain-embedded launch insurance, respectively? How to price the launch service contract for the satellite operator? Furthermore, how to make the optimal decision for the vehicle manufacturer? \par
RQ2. How does the government arrange subsidies? And how does the subsidy affect the optimal decisions?\par
RQ3. When will the blockchain launch platform be feasible and how does it affect the optimal decisions? \par
RQ4. What are the subsidy or blockchain values for the satellite operator, the vehicle manufacturer and customers, respectively?
%When will the presence of the blockchain launch platform achieve a win-win in which both the satellite operator, and the vehicle manufacturer are beneficial?\par
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
To address the above research questions, we conduct a game-theoretic analytical study by building math models.
By arithmetic derivation and analysis, we obtain the following results:
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
\begin{enumerate} [(1)]
\item When government subsidies for the selection of satellite operators for low-cost vehicle launches, it helps to form positive feedback in the commercial satellite market,
that is, the satellite vendor is more willing to pay high launch prices, so that the vehicle manufacture have the motivation to increase the probability of successful launches.
\item Once the government subsidy project is launched, the satellite operator will always get more from it than before.
But for the vehicle manufacturer, only when the cost of vehicle is relatively low, his income will increase compared to before; otherwise, he cannot benefit from the subsidy program.
For consumers, there is no change in consumer surplus.
Therefore, the overall social welfare as the sum of the profit of the various subjects will increase.
\item In the blockchain-embedded model, the values that blockchain bring to the optimal decisions are similar to the government subsidy brings.
However, there is one difference to claim that the retail price has been increased and the market demand also increases.
\item Moreover, for the satellite, she will always benefit from the adoption of blockchain if its cost is relatively low.
\item However, the profitable condition for the vehicle to decide whether use the blockchain is not only the cost of blockchain is expensive but also the cost of vehicle manufacturing is low.
\item Significantly, the use of the blockchain launch platform will make the consumer surplus increase no matter in which situation.
\end{enumerate}
%(1) When the anti-risk ability of the satellite operator is enhanced, the profits of both the satellite operator and the vehicle manufacturer will increase.
%Significantly, the implementation of the blockchain launch platform will make this effect more pronounced.
%Moreover, the adoption of blockchain will decrease the threshold of the satellite operator to set the optimal price.
%(2) Particularly, the optimal effort the vehicle manufacturer exert will increase and the contract price as well as the premium rate will decrease with the support of blockchain.
%(3) Via analyzing the value of blockchain, we note that the blockchain launch platform will always benefit the satellite operator no matter how weak her risk resistance is.
%However, it is profitable for the vehicle manufacturer to implement cost-advantage blockchain technology only when the satellite operator has a strong capacity for risk.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
\section{Literature review}\label{sec:review}
Our paper is closely related to three research streams: supply chain insurance, space supply chain management and blockchain. We review them as follows.
\subsection{Supply chain insurance}
Our paper is closely related to the topic of insurance adopted to manage disruptive risk, which is a stream of supply chain finance.
For a comprehensive overview, we refer readers to read \cite{Wang2021b}, \cite{Chakuu2019}, \cite{Xu2018}, \cite{Gelsomino2016}, \cite{Zhao2015}, and \cite{Gomm2010}.
As a financial derivative instrument of risk aversion, insurance contracts can be seen as hedging at the expense of current profits and improving the risk tolerance by compensating the economic losses of enterprises when the supply chain disrupt caused by internal (e.g., the quality of products, the interruption of funds, and the disruption of logistic) or external (e.g., the change of weather, the pandemic of COVID-19, and the change of market) risks \citep{Sodhi2012a, Heckmann2015}.\par
According to the type of risks, the literature of supply chain insurance contracts can be reducible to two categories.
(1) One is to hedge internal risks by combining insurance contracts with supply chain contracts.
As insurance contracts could coordinate the supply chain \citep{Lin2010}, researchers compared it with the revenue sharing contract according to different agents risk aversion based on the newsvendor model.
Besides, \cite{Wang2021} also discussed which contract is better for the supply chain partners between the advanced payment contract, penalty contract, and time insurance contract in the express delivery supply chain.\par
(2) Another is to study the trade-off between high commercial insurance and the substantial economic losses caused by external risks.
The typical market risk of demand uncertainty is a thorny question that the newsvendor model faces thus \cite{LodreeJr2008} design an insurance policy framework to quantify the risks and benefits, which give decision-makers a practical approach to prepare for supply chain disruptions.
Moreover, \cite{Yu2021} considered the interrupt probability of the supply chain and illustrate the value of business interruption insurance which increases the profit of each participant.
\cite{Brusset2018} constructed a weather index through case studies that transfer entrepreneurial risk to other risk-takers through insurance or options contracts.
Similar to these researches, our paper also adopts the insurance contract to hedge the interrupt risk while the focal point is in the space launch supply chain, which is remarkable for technical complexity, high quality \& reliability requirements, and colossal failure losses.
%However, we also combine the blockchain technology with supply chain management which is timely and important.
\subsection{Space supply chain management}
At present, supply chain management in space era is initiated by research institutes, universities and researchers.
Such as China Aerospace Industry Corporation, European Space Agency and Indian Space Research Organisation conducted a series of research on space supply chain management \citep{Kucukcay}.
Moreover one of the famous works is the Interplanetary Supply Chain Management and Logistics Architectures project from \cite{MIT}, which develops an integrated supply chain management framework for space logistics.\par
According to the types of existing studies in this topic, they can be reducible to two categories:\par
(1) One kind of research focuses on optimizing the operating system to improve the efficiency from mathematical models and simulation.
\cite{Galluzzi2006} regarded supply chain management as a critical piece of framework in the aerospace industry, and they elaborated the pattern operation in this area.
\cite{Taylor2006} also designed and evaluated the operating system in the space supply chain, but they primarily engaged in optimizing delivery operation, which sustains the exploration initiative.
Moreover, \cite{Gralla2006} gave a comprehensive model and simulation of the supply chain management implemented in the aerospace industry, which is low-volume and schedule-driven compared to the high-volume and market demand-driven SCM in the commercial sector.\par
(2) Another type of study starred in analyzing the business problem in supply chain management. The research on this topic is relatively few.
\cite{Wooten2018} examined the space industry's operation management, which involves manufacturing operations, supply chain management, and sustainable operations. Besides, they also outlined the challenges and essential questions related to stakeholders.
\cite{Raghunath2021} discussed the challenges that commercial space operation faces from a business perspective.
Furthermore, \cite{Guo2021} comprehensively analyzed the global aerospace industry's current situation and future development from the upstream supply chain, midstream production chain, and downstream application chain.
In addition, \cite{Donelli2021} considered the profitability and efficiency during the aircraft manufacturing and supply chain. The paper proposed a model-based approach to optimal the multiple-choice.
Furthermore, \cite{Dewicki} also based on operational management analyze the business model in commercial space. \par
As review literature, most papers target SCM in space give the mathematical model from optimizing logistics, even the system flow. While our paper builds models from the business angle, we concentrate on the game theory between participants during the launch activity.
\subsection{Blockchain technology support supply chain management}
% congbudong jiaodu d qukuail yanjiu;
As a “trust ledger”, blockchain has overwhelming advantage of data storage such as openness, transparency, tampering, and traceability, which make it possible to manipulate higher quality data \citep{Choi2019}, improving the supply chain efficiency and so on \citep{Chod2020}.
According to its characters, \cite{Queiroz2019,Wang2019,Babich2020, Li2022} gave the review of this topic.\par
Besides, more and more scholars have begun to study the application of blockchain in the supply chain.
(1) Inside the supply chain, (i) in upriver, blockchain technology facilitates the flow of raw materials from the suppliers \citep{ Naydenova2017, Nash2016};
(ii) in the midstream, it promotes the exchange of manufacture information and design smart contracts between participants in the supply chain upstream and downstream and achieve coordination eventually \citep{Moise2018, Hilary2022, Chod2020,Korpela2017,Wang2021a}.
(2) Outside the supply chain,
(i) face the third party, it provides an innovative way for the capital constraint companies to finance \citep{Choi2020,Choi2021};
(ii) face the market, it helps products to fight counterfeits, earn trust of customers and win company reputation in the market \citep{Pun2021, Shen2021,Fan2020}.\par
Regarding our topic, this article mainly refers to articles on the application of blockchain in the space supply chain.
\cite{Adhikari2020} gave a clearly analysis on the implementation of blockchain in the area of space cybersecurity framework against global positioning system spoofing.
\cite{Zheng2021} studied a three-tier space supply chain under the decision-making problem and investigated how blockchain technology optimizes decisions based on information sharing.
Moreover, \cite{HylandWood2020} examined three potential blockchain properties applied in space: real-time communication during the interplanetary space operating and operations realm of the solar system.
However, different from them, this article's focal point is on launching a service supply chain supported by fintech ( blockchain-embedded insurance) to facilitate launching risks and contract pricing.
\subsection{Summary}
Supply chain insurance and blockchain technology adoption are essential topics in space launch operation management.
Motivated by real-world blockchain application such as IBM and Cloud Constellation Corporation are working together to build a blockchain-based platform in the space launch supply chain, this paper theoretically investigates the blockchain-embedded insurance model operations.
The insights not only contribute to the literature in operation management but also advance the industrial knowledge regarding blockchain launch platforms.\par
The following parts in this paper are organized as:
\refsec{sec:models} establishes the main models and investigates corresponding optimal decisions, one for insurance model (model I) and the other for blockchain-embedded insurance model (Model B).
\refsec{sec:value} further demonstrates the effect on optimal decisions and value for participants brought by the blockchain-embedded launch platform.
\refsec{sec:conclusions} concludes this study and gives analytical insights.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
\section{Benchmark case} \label{sec:models}
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
Consider a make-to-order supply chain consisting of one vehicle manufacturer (VM, he), one satellite operator (SO, she) and an insurance company (IC, it).
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
As shown in \reffig{fig:sequence}, to launch the satellite successfully, the SO usually conducts a series analyses to choose the vehicle and design the launch service contract with launch price $l$ and prepay ratio $\alpha$.
Once the satellite is on-track, the SO will pay VM last part $(1-\alpha)p$ and she will obtain income from sailing satellite data.
Without loss generality, consumers possess a stochastic valuation $u$ towards the satellite data, which follows a distribution $f(u)$. Following most literature, we set $f(u)$ follows a uniform distribution with a rage of $0-1$, denoted by $U[0,1]$. To avoid facing messy mathematics, we normalize the consumer population as $1$.
% the SO has already signed contracts future servicing missions at income $F$ before launching \citep{SpaceFund2022}, which rely on satellite service to function. So the satellite income also is one factor that SO needs to consider while designing the launch contract, which is an indicator of her risk resistance \citep{Li2010}. \par
As common in launch activity, our models capture two typical features in the space supply chain.
First, the launch activity is risky, which means there is a probability for the satellite operating in its final orbital position.
The VM can improve the probability of mission success (aka reliability) by exerting costly efforts (e.g., improving technologies, equipment or processes) \citep{Bailey2020, Kunstadter2020}.
Following \cite{Tang2018}, we scale the base launch success probability to 0.
To increase the probability from 0 to $e$, where $e \in (0, 1)$, the VM needs to exert effort associated with a disutility (cost of effort) $ke^2$ with $k > 0$. The setting of such a disutility is common in many models.\par
Notedly, a launch failure is costly to all involved parties. For the SO, she will lost her satellite and the income.
For the VM, what he will face is not only the current contract loss but also the damage of his reputation and future business as well as financing.
To reflect the VM's additional loss, a penalty denoted by $\theta$ is adopted into the profit function. %\textcolor{red}{cite:Williams-Robert-COVERING-THE-INCREASED-LIABILITY-OF-NEW-LAUNCH-MARKETS.pdf}
Considering the launch risk, it is natural that SO attempts to purchase launch insurance before launching to hedge risks.
IC designs the launch insurance according to the analyses of conducting serious technological analyses of satellite and the VM.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
Once the launch fails, the IC usually pays pro rate compensation.
We assume the claim covers $\beta$ of the whole loss including the cost of satellite and the prepay price.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
We summarize the notation used throughout the paper in \reftab{tab:Parameters}.
\begin{table}[htbp]
\scriptsize
\caption{\label{tab:Parameters} Notation}
\centering
\begin{threeparttable}
\begin{tabular}{ll} % lcr: left, center, right
\toprule
Variable & Remark\\
\midrule
Model I & Satellite launch supply chain with insurance\\
Model IG& Satellite launch supply chain with government-subsidized insurance \\
Model B & Blockchain-embedded satellite launch supply chain with insurance \\
Model BG & Blockchain-embedded satellite launch supply chain with government-subsidized insurance \\
$d$ & The benefit of satellite data brought to customers\\
$p$ & The satellite data retail price \\
$l$ & The launching service price \\
$\alpha$ & The upfront payment ratio \\
$e$& The “rate of successful launch ”, which is the same as “the level of effort the VM exerting” in this paper \\
$k$& The cost coefficient of effort\\
$r$ &The premium rate \\
$g$& The government-subsidized launch insurance premium rates\\
$c_i$& The cost of VM $(i= V)$ or SO $(i= S)$ \\
%\textcolor{red}{Payment for a launch is usually subdivided in several installments. A first rate will usually be charged upon reservation of a certain flight opportunity, while the second one is due upon launch service agreement signature. As soon as the ICD is finalized, a third rate applies and the final part is charged when the launch has been performed.}
$\theta$ & The penalty of a failed launch for VM\\
$k$ & The effort cost factor\\
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
$\pi_i$ & The profit of vehicle manufacture$(i= V)$ or satellite operator $(i= S)$ or insurance company $(i=I)$\\
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
$CS$& The consumer surplus\\
$SW$& The social welfare\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\begin{tablenotes}
\item[a] Subscripts $S$, $V$ and $I$ are the indices of SO, VM and IC respectively.
\item[b] Superscript $I$, $IG$, $B$ and $BG$ to describe function and decisions in model I, model IG, model B and model BG respectively.
\end{tablenotes}
\end{threeparttable}
\end{table}
% TODO: \usepackage{graphicx} required
\begin{figure}[H]
\centering
\includegraphics[width=1\linewidth]{sequences.pdf}
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
\caption{Sequence of events. SO :the satellite operator; VM: the vehicle manufacture; IC: the insurance company. }
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
\label{fig:sequence}
\end{figure}
\subsection{Model I: Satellite launch supply chain with insurance } \label{sec:modeli}
Acting as the Stackelberg leader, the SO sets the contract terms and the VM, as the follower, decides whether to accept the contract.
Without loss of generality, we focus on the following contract: the SO pays the VM a certain $\alpha$ of launch price $l$ upfront when launch services are procured. \citep{Andrews2011,Barschke2020}
Furthermore, when the launch is successful, the VM then receives the balance of the payment $(1-\alpha)*l$ for services or $0$ otherwise.
Concerning risk, the SO buys the launch insurance with the premium rate $r$ to compensate the loss if the launch failed. \reffig{fig:sequence} shows the sequence of events corresponding to the game model.
Therefore, the market demand and payoff function, $D^I$ and $\pis$, faces by the SO can be measured as follows:
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:id}
% \left\{
\begin{aligned}
D^I &= 1 \int_{p-d}^{1}{f\left( u \right) \mathrm{d} u}= 1-p+d \\
\end{aligned}
% \right.
\end{eqnarray}
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:iso:payoff}
% \left\{
\begin{aligned}
\max_{l,p} \E [\pis(l, p, e, r)] &= epD -[\alpha + e(1-\alpha) ]l - r (\cs + \alpha l) + (1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l)- \cs,\\
% s.t.~pD &\geq \cs + l
\end{aligned}
% \right.
\end{eqnarray}
As shown, $\pis$ consists of five parts:
(1) the income she can obtain once the satellite works in orbit $epD$;
(2) the expect launch service price $[\alpha+e(1-\alpha)]l$;
(3) the premium for the launch insurance $ r (\cs + \alpha l)$;
(4) the compensate she will get once the launch failed $(1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l) $.
(5) the cost of building the satellite $ \cs$.
Without loss of generality, the satellite income covers its building and launch cost; i.e., the SO sets a contract only when $pD\geq\cs + l $.\par
As depicted in \reffig{fig:sequence}, the VM accepts a contract with price $l$ and receives the prepayment $\alpha*l$ from the SO, then he manufactures the rocket which cost $c_v$.
If the vehicle launch successfully, he receives the last $(1-\alpha )*l$ from the SO.
If launching is failed, the VM not only receives no payment but also suffers penalty which monetized as $\theta$ .
Therefore, the VMs objective is to maximize his expected payoff $\piv$ as follows:
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:vm:payoff}
% \left\{
\begin{aligned}
\max_e \E [\piv(l, p, e)] &=[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha) ]l - (1 - e) \theta - (ke^2 + \cv),\\
s.t.~\piv &\geq 0
\end{aligned}
% \right.
\end{eqnarray}
As shown, $\piv$ consists of three parts: (1) the prepaid income and expected gain upon successful launch $[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha) ]l$,
(2) the expected loss of failure penalty in the event of launch failure $(1 - e) \theta$, and (3) the cost of effort and vehicle $ke^2 + \cv$.
The non-negative profit constraint ensures the profitability of launch successfully; otherwise, the VM will quit the cooperation.
\subsubsection{The VMs effort}
We now solve the Stackelberg game as depicted in \reffig{fig:sequence} using backward induction.
First, given any launch price $l$, by considering the first-order condition of \refequ{eq:vm:payoff}, the VMs best response is given as:
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:ei} %\nonumber
e(l)&=\frac{(1-\alpha)l+\theta}{2k},\\
~s.t.&0<e\leq 1. \label{eq:ec}
\end{eqnarray}\par
%Noted, there is a constraint for effort $e$ that \refequ{eq:ec} which means the successful launch rate should be non-negative and below the upper bound, that is satisfied with the case in practice. By simplifying this constraint, we can get the interval of $\alpha$ that $[\underline{\alpha},\overline{\alpha}]$, and the final simplified form is summarized in \reflem{lemma:modeli}.
By substituting \refequ{eq:ei} into the VMs payoff $\piv$ given in \refequ{eq:vm:payoff}, it can be obtained that:
\begin{eqnarray}
\piv=\frac{[(1-\alpha)l+\theta]^2}{4k}+\alpha l-\theta-\cv
\end{eqnarray}\par
Hence, considering the VM's participation constraint, i.e., $\piv \geq0$ , the lowest VMs acceptance (VA) launch price can be written as:
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:pv}
l \geq l_{VA} \equiv \frac{2\omega-2\alpha k-(1-\alpha) \theta}{(1-\alpha)^2},
\end{eqnarray}
where $\omega=\sqrt{k[(1-\alpha)^2 \cv+ \alpha ^2 k + (1-\alpha) \theta]}$.
\subsubsection{The IC's premium rate}
Observing the contract price $l$ selected by the SO, the insurance company can anticipate the VMs effort $e(l)$ as given in \eqref{eq:ei}.
Operating in a competitive market, the insurer sets its rate $r$ to break-even in expectation.
In other words, under the rate $r$ that it offers, the insurance companys expected payoff, $r (\cs + \alpha l)$, equals the amount of coverage, $ (1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l)$.
Thus IC's profit function and the premium rate can be written as:
\begin{eqnarray}
\begin{aligned}
\pi_i^I&= r (\cs + \alpha l)-(1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l),\\
r(l)&= \beta[1-\frac{(1-\alpha)l+\theta}{2k}].\label{eq:ri}\\
\end{aligned}
\end{eqnarray}
\subsubsection{The SO's optimal price}
Anticipating the VMs best response $e$ given in \eqref{eq:ei} and the premium rate \eqref{eq:ri}, the SOs payoff given in \refequ{eq:iso:payoff} can be rewritten as:
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:so:payoff_p}
\begin{aligned}
\max_p \E [ \pis (l, p)] &=\ds \frac{[pD-(1-\alpha)l]*[(1-\alpha)l+\theta]}{2k} - \alpha l-\cs,\\
~ l &\geq l_{VA}.\\
\end{aligned}
\end{eqnarray}
Checking the Hessian matrix of SO's payoff, we find $\pis$ is concave in $l$ and $p$ jointly when $0 < k < \frac{(1-\alpha)[(1+d)^2+ \theta]}{8\alpha}$.
In this paper, we focus on the case when the condition is met.
According to the assume, we can get the optimal launch price and optimal retail price for her which are $l_{S}=\frac{\phi-8\theta(1-\alpha)}{8(1-\alpha)^2}$ and $p^*=\frac{1+d}{2}$, where $\phi=(1-\alpha)(1+d)^2+(1-\alpha)4\theta-8\alpha k$.
Consider the constraints, the SO aims to select the optimal contract price $l^* = \max(l_S, l_{VA}) $ that maximizes her payoff, given in \refequ{eq:so:payoff_p}. The optimal contract and corresponding equilibrium outcomes are given in \reflem{lemma:modeli}.
According to the above derivation, we can also obtain the consumer surplus and social welfare as follows:
\begin{eqnarray}
\begin{aligned}
CS^I &= 1 \int_{p-d}^{1}[u-(p-d)]{f\left( u \right) \mathrm{d} u}=\frac{(1+d)^2}{8},\label{eq:CS} \\
SW^I &=\pis+\piv+CS^I. \\
\end{aligned}
\end{eqnarray}
By denoting all of the functions, we obtain \reflem{lemma:modeli}.
\begin{lem} \label{lemma:modeli}
The equilibrium outcomes of Model I are shown in \reftab{tab:modeli_decisions}.
\end{lem}
\begin{table*}[htbp]
\scriptsize
% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
\newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
\caption{\label{tab:modeli_decisions} The equilibrium outcomes in Model I.}
\centering
\renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
\begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{c}@{}}
\toprule
& \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ (i.e., $l_S>l_{VA}$) } & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ (i.e., $I_{VA} \geq l_S$ ) } \\
\midrule
Effort of VM exerting $e^*$&
$\frac{\phi}{16(1-\alpha)k}$ &
$\frac{\omega-\alpha k }{(1-\alpha)k}$ \\
Launch price $l^*$&
$l^*=l_{S}=\frac{\phi-8\theta(1-\alpha)}{8(1-\alpha)^2}$&
$ l^*=l_{VA}= \frac{2\omega-2\alpha k-(1-\alpha) \theta}{(1-\alpha)^2}$\\
Retail price $p^*$&
$\frac{1+d}{2}$&
$\frac{1+d}{2}$\\
Premium rate $r^*$&
$\beta(1-\frac{\phi}{16(1-\alpha)k})$&
$\beta\frac{k-\omega}{(1-\alpha)k}$\\
SO's profit $\pis$&
$\frac{\phi^2}{128(1-\alpha)^2k}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)} -\cs$&
$\frac{(\omega-\alpha k)(\phi+8\alpha k-8\omega)}{4(1-\alpha )^2k}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-\cs$\\
VM's profit $\piv$&
$\frac{\phi^2+32\alpha k\phi}{256(1-\alpha)^2k}-\frac{ \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-\cv$&
$0$\\
Consumer surplus $CS$&
$\frac{(1+d)^2}{8}$&
$\frac{(1+d)^2}{8}$&\\
Social welfare $SW$&
$\frac{3\phi^2+32\alpha k\phi}{256(1-\alpha)^2k}- \theta-\cs-\cv+\frac{(1+d)^2}{8}$&
$\frac{(\omega-\alpha k)(\phi+8\alpha k-8\omega)}{4(1-\alpha )^2k}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-\cs+\frac{(1+d)^2}{8}$\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\begin{tablenotes}
\item To avoid complicated writing, we define
$\phi=(1-\alpha)(1+d)^2+4(1-\alpha)\theta-8\alpha k$,
$\omega=\sqrt{(1-\alpha)^2k\cv+\alpha ^2k^2-(1-\alpha)k\theta}$.
\end{tablenotes}
\end{table*}
Note that there are two cases in our equilibrium result that $\cv<H(\alpha) $ and $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, where $H(\alpha)=\frac{(1+d)^4(1-\alpha)^2+(1+d)^2+8(1-\alpha)[2\alpha k+\theta(1-\alpha)]+16\theta^2(1-\alpha)^2-192\alpha^2k^2-64\theta k(1-\alpha)(4-\alpha)}{256(1-\alpha)^2k}$.
This is due to the launch price $l^* = \max(l_S, l_{VA})$.
In the first case, the optimal launch price $l_S$ fixed by the SO is higher than $l_{VA}$, which means the contract launch price $l^*$ is $l_S$ equaling $\cv <H(\alpha)$.
In the second case, SO's optimal launch price $l_S$ is lower than $l_{VA}$, so she has to fix the contract price $l^*$ as $l_{VA}$ to avoid the profit of VM being negative; otherwise the VM will quit the cooperation.
% the sesitivity analyses of "d"
According to the equilibrium outcomes, we now conduct the sensitivity analyses for Model I and summarized the outcomes in \reftab{tab:modeli_and_ig_sensitivity}.
Firstly, we examine how the benefit of satellite data brought to customers affects the optimal VM' effort, premium rate, launch price, and retail price.
We have the following findings: if the benefit of satellite data brought to customers $d$ increases,
(a) when the manufacturing cost of the vehicle $\cv$ is satisfied with $\cv< H(\alpha)$:
(i) the effort of VM exerting $e^*$, the launch price $l^*$, and the retail price $p^*$ will all monotonically increase;
(ii) the premium rate $r^*$ will decrease monotonically;
(b) when $\cv\geq H(\alpha)$:
(i) the retail price $p^*$ will increase;
(ii) but the effort of VM exerting $e^*$, the launch price $l^*$, and the premium rate $r^*$ do not change.
In the first situation that the cost of the vehicle is satisfied with $\cv< H(\alpha)$ (i.e. $l^*=l_S$), intuitively, when customers benefit more from the satellite data, the retail price $p$ set by SO will increase.
Furthermore, she will be willing to pay more for VM, which leads to a high launch price $l$.
Then the VM' s motivation to increase the probability of a successful launch will also increase.
The insurance premium rate $r$ will also decrease based on the successful launch probability increase.
In the second situation $\cv\geq H(\alpha)$ (i.e. $l^*=l_{VA}$ ), the launch price just satisfied the VM's acceptance line .
The launch price $l$ and the effort $e$ are depend on the VM instead of the SO, so they are not affect by the benefit brought to customers $d$.
As the premium rate $r$ is set according to the effort $e$, thus it also does not change with $d$ in this situation.
However, the retail price $p$ steal increases because it is relative to the customers closely.
% the sesitivity analyses of "k"
Nextly, we explore how the cost coefficient of effort $k$ affects the equilibrium outcomes mentioned above.
If the cost coefficient of effort $k$ increases,
(a) no matter what the manufacturing cost of the vehicle $\cv$ is,
(i) the effort exerted by the VM $e$ and the launch price $l$ will always decrease;
(ii) the premium rate $r$ will always increase;
(iii) the retail price $p$ does not change all the time;
(b) however, the effects on launch price $l$ are different in the two situations;
(i) when $\cv< H(\alpha)$ (i.e. $l^*=l_S$), the launch price $l$ will decrease;
(ii) otherwise, it will increase.
As the cost coefficient of effort $k$ increases, the VM will exert less effort. So no matter the situation, the effort $e$ always decreases with the increase of $k$.
However, the changes in launch price $l$ are different when $\cv$ satisfies different conditions.
That is because the body that determines the launch price has changed.
When $\cv<H(\alpha)$, it is the SO to decide the launch price that she will decrease the contract price according to the decrease of effort $e$.
But when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, the launch price is the VM's acceptance line, which means it is the VM to decide the launch price $l$, so he will increase the contract price to compensate for the increase of effort cost.
For the premium rate, the IC sets it according to the effort $e$, so it will increase with the decreasing successful launch probability.
As the retail price is not relative to the effort cost coefficient, there is no change in retail price $p$.
% the sensitivity analyses of "$\theta$"
Then we analyze how penalty cost $\theta$ affects these optimal outcomes.
If the failed-launch penalty $\theta$ increases,
(a) no matter what the manufacturing cost of the vehicle $\cv$ is,
(i) the effort exerted by the VM $e$ and the launch price $l$ will always increase;
(ii) the premium rate $r$ will always decrease;
(iii) the retail price $p$ does not change all the time;
(b) however, the effects on launch price $l$ are different in the two situations;
(i) when $\cv< H(\alpha)$ (i.e. $l^*=l_S$), the launch price $l$ will decrease;
(ii) otherwise, it will increase.
Noted, the effect of $\theta$ to $e$ is similar to $k$, but the change is the opposite: no matter the situation, the effort $e$ always increases with the increase of $\theta$.
That is because the VM has to exert more effort to increase the successful launch probability to avoid the expensive failed-launch penalty $\theta$.
The change of launch price $l$ in these two situations is the same as $k$ affects it.
However, the internal cause of its change is different.
When $\cv<H(\alpha)$, it is the SO to decide the launch price that she don't need to increase the launch price $l$ as the VM will increase effort $e$ spontaneously with the increasing of $\theta$.
But when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, the launch price is the VM's acceptance line, which means it is the VM to decide the launch price $l$, so he will increase the contract price to compensate for the increase of failed-launch penalty.
For the premium rate, the IC sets it according to the effort $e$, so it will decrease with the increasing successful launch probability.
As the retail price is not relative to the penalty cost, there is no change in retail price $p$.
Under model I, by deriving different factors' sensitivity analyses on payoffs we have following findings:
(a) When the benefit satellite data brings to customers increases, both SO's and VM's profits increase.
Noted, the consumer surplus $CS$ also increases which is the only one condition that can benefit the customers. Therefore, we will not analyze the impact of other factors on consumer surplus $CS$.
As a result, the social welfare $SW$, the sum of the three parts, will increases with $d$ naturally.
(b) If the cost coefficient of effort $k$ increases,
(i) VM's profit and social welfare always decrease;
(ii) for the SO, in the situation $\cv<H(\alpha)$, her profit will increase when $k<k_1$, where $k_1= \frac{(1-\alpha)[(1+d)^2+4\theta]}{8\alpha}$, otherwise $\pis$ will decrease when $k \geq k_1$;
in the other situation $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, SO's profit decreases.
(c) As the increasing of $\theta$,
(i) SO's profit always increases;
(ii) for the VM and society, in the situation $\cv<H(\alpha)$, their profits will increase when $\theta$ satisfies with $\theta<\theta_{V1}$ and $\theta<\theta_{W1}$, respectively, where $\theta_{V1}=\frac{32k-(1-\alpha)(1+d)^2-8\alpha k}{4(1-\alpha)}$ and $\theta_{W1}=\frac{32k-3(1-\alpha)(1+d)^2-24\alpha k}{12(1-\alpha)}$, otherwise they both will decrease; in the other situation $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, $\pis$ and $SW$ will decreases.
\begin{table*}[htbp]
\scriptsize
% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
\newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
\caption{\label{tab:modeli_and_ig_sensitivity} Sensitivity analyses for Model I and Model IG.}
\centering
\renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
\begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}}
\toprule
& {Model}&{Situation}&{$e^*$}&{$r^*$}&{$l^*$}&{$p^*$} &{$\pi_S$}&{$\pi_V$}&{$CS$}&{$SW$} \\
\midrule
$d \uparrow$ &
Model I &{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
-&-&-&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
&Model IG& {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
-&-&-&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
$k \uparrow$ &
Model I &{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$: $k<k_1$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$\\
&&&&&&&$\uparrow :k\geq k_1$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$}
&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$-$&$\downarrow$\\
&Model IG& {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\downarrow : 0<g<1$&$-$&$\downarrow$: $k<k_2$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$\\
&&&&&$-:g=1$&&$\uparrow :k\geq k_2$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$\\
$\theta \uparrow$&
Model I &{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow: \theta<\theta_{V1}$&$-$&$\uparrow: \theta<\theta_{W1}$\\
&&&&&&&&$\downarrow: \theta \geq \theta_{V1}$&&$\downarrow: \theta \geq \theta_{W1}$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$}&
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$-$&$\uparrow$\\
&Model IG& {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow: \theta<\theta_{V2}$&$-$&$\uparrow: \theta<\theta_{W2}$\\
&&&&&&&&$\downarrow: \theta \geq \theta_{V2}$&&$\downarrow: \theta \geq \theta_{W2}$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$}&
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$-$&$\uparrow$\\
$g \uparrow$&
Model IG& {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$}&
$-$&$-$&$-$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$-$&$\uparrow$\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\end{table*}
\subsection{Model IG: Satellite launch supply chain with government-subsidized insurance}
Based on the practical observation of the real world, we build model IG in which we consider the situation that the government, aiming to promote the development of the commercial space industry, launches the commercial space launch insurance subsidy program.
The event sequence is similar to the model I which is illustrated in \reffig{fig:sequence_g}, but there is a change: after the IC decides the premium rate $r$, the government will determine a subsidized rate $g$.
So the only difference between model I and model IG is that the SO will obtain an insurance subsidy $g$.
% TODO: \usepackage{graphicx} required
\begin{figure}[H]
\centering
\includegraphics[width=1\linewidth]{sequences_g.pdf}
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
\caption{Sequence of events. SO :the satellite operator; VM: the vehicle manufacture; IC: the insurance company. }
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
\label{fig:sequence_g}
\end{figure}
Thus the market demand is given as follows:
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:igd}
% \left\{
\begin{aligned}
D^{IG} &= 1 \int_{p^{IG}-d}^{1}{f\left( u \right) \mathrm{d} u}= 1-p^{IG}+d \\
\end{aligned}
% \right.
\end{eqnarray}
Then the members' payoffs can be measured as follows:
\begin{eqnarray}
\begin{aligned}
\pgs &= epD -[\alpha + e(1-\alpha) ]l - (r-g) (\cs + \alpha l) + (1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l)- \cs,\label{eq:igso:payoff}\\
\pi_i^{IG}&= r (\cs + \alpha l)-(1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l),\\
\pgv&=[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha) ]l - (1 - e) \theta - (ke^2 + \cv),\label{eq:igvm:payoff}\\
s.t.~\pgv &\geq 0
\end{aligned}
\end{eqnarray}
Following the similar derivation in \ref{sec:modeli}, we obtain the equilibrium outcomes which are summarized in \reflem{lemma:modelig}.
\begin{lem} \label{lemma:modelig}
The equilibrium outcomes of Model IG are shown in \reftab{tab:modelig_decisions}.
\end{lem}
\begin{table*}[htbp]
\scriptsize
% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
\newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
\caption{\label{tab:modelig_decisions} The equilibrium outcomes in Model IG.}
\centering
\renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
\begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{c}@{}}
\toprule
& \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ } \\
\midrule
Effort of VM exerting $e^*$&
$\frac{\psi}{16(1-\alpha)k}$ &
$\frac{\omega-\alpha k }{(1-\alpha)k}$ \\
Launch price $l^*$&
$l^*=l_{S}=\frac{\psi-8\theta(1-\alpha)}{8(1-\alpha)^2}$&
$ l^*=l_{VA}= \frac{2\omega-2\alpha k-(1-\alpha) \theta}{(1-\alpha)^2}$\\
Retail price $p^*$&
$\frac{1+d}{2}$&
$\frac{1+d}{2}$\\
Premium rate $r^*$&
$\beta(1-\frac{\psi}{16(1-\alpha)k})$&
$\beta\frac{k-\omega}{(1-\alpha)k}$\\
SO's profit $\pgs$&
$\frac{\psi^2}{128(1-\alpha)^2k}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)} -(1-g)\cs$&
$\frac{(\omega-\alpha k)(\psi+8\alpha k-8\omega)}{4(1-\alpha )^2k}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-(1-g)\cs$\\
VM's profit $\pgv$&
$\frac{\psi^2+32\alpha k\psi}{256(1-\alpha)^2k}-\frac{ \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-\cv$&
$0$\\
Consumer surplus $CS^{IG}$&
$\frac{(1+d)^2}{8}$&
$\frac{(1+d)^2}{8}$&\\
Social welfare $SW^{IG}$&
$\frac{3\psi^2+32\alpha k\psi}{256(1-\alpha)^2k}- \frac{\theta[1-(1-g)\alpha]}{1-\alpha}-(1-g)\cs-\cv+\frac{(1+d)^2}{8}$&
$\frac{(\omega-\alpha k)(\psi+8\alpha k-8\omega)}{4(1-\alpha )^2k}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-(1-g)\cs+\frac{(1+d)^2}{8}$\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\begin{tablenotes}
\item To avoid complicated writing, we define
$\psi=(1-\alpha)(1+d)^2+4(1-\alpha)\theta-8\alpha k(1-g)$,
$\omega=\sqrt{(1-\alpha)^2k\cv+\alpha ^2k^2-(1-\alpha)k\theta}$.
\end{tablenotes}
\end{table*}
Observing the optimal decisions of model IG are similar to that of model I, but there are three points worthy of notice.
(i) When $\cv<H(\alpha)$, the successful launch probability $e$ and launch price $l$ increase as each has a positive increment, as $\psi>\phi$. The premium rate $r$ will decrease, affected by government subsidy.
(ii) When $\cv\geq H(\alpha)$, the successful launch probability, launch price, and the premium rate do not affect by the government subsidy.
(iii) No matter the situation, the retail price doesn't change, which means the government subsidy program doesn't affect the market retail price.
We will talk about the difference between model I and model IG in detail in \refsec{sec:values_g}.
We now report the sensitivity analysis performing as shown in \reftab{tab:modeli_and_ig_sensitivity}.
We find that the results of Model IG and Model I were very similar, but with three difference.
Firstly, if the cost coefficient of effort $k$ increases,
(i) when $0<g<1$, the launch price $l$ will decrease in the first situation $\cv<H(\alpha)$;
however, when $g=1$, which means the subsidy wholly covers the insurance, the launch price will not be affected by $k$;
(ii) the threshold $k_2$ of SO's profit $\pgs$ to change direction is higher than $k_1$, where $k_2=\frac{(1-\alpha)[(1+d)^2+4\theta]}{8\alpha(1-g)}$.
Secondly, if the launch-fail penalty $\theta$ increases,
in the situation $\cv<H(\alpha)$, the thresholds of $\pgv$ and $SW^{IG}$, $\theta_{V2}$ and $\theta_{W2}$ are both higher than these of model I, where $\theta_{V2}=\frac{32k-(1-\alpha)(1+d)^2-8\alpha k(1-g)}{4(1-\alpha)}$ and $\theta_{W2}=\frac{32k-3(1-\alpha)(1+d)^2-24\alpha k(1-g)}{12(1-\alpha)}$. That means the VM and society can bear a higher penalty when the government launch the subsidy program.
Thirdly, if the subsidy rate $g$ increases,
(i) when $\cv<h(\alpha)$, the successful launch probability $e$ and the launch price $l$ will increase, the premium rate $r$ will decrease; the SO's profit $\pgs$, the VM's profit $\pgv$ and social welfare $SW^{IG}$ will increase;
(ii)when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, all of the optimal decisions are not affected.
(iii) no matter in which situation, the consumer surplus do not change which means the government subsidy program can't benefit the customers.
\subsection{Values of government subsidies}\label{sec:values_g}
In order to better explore the value of government subsidies, we explored $VSO$, $VVM$, $CS$, and $SW$ as following, which represent the benefits that government subsidies bring to the SO, the VM, customers, and the society, respectively.
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:values_g}
\begin{aligned}
VSO&=\pgs-\pis\\
VVM&=\pgv-\piv\\
VCS&=CS^{IG}-CS^I\\
VSW&=SW^{IG}-SW^I\\
\end{aligned}
\end{eqnarray}
We report the results in \reftab{tab:values_g} by comparing the equilibrium outcomes between model I and model IG.
After analyzing the results, we obtain \refprop{prop:values_decision} and \refprop{prop:values_profit}.
\begin{table*}[htbp]
\scriptsize
% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
\newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
\caption{\label{tab:values_g} Values of government subsidies.}
\centering
\renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
\begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}}
\toprule
&{Situation}&{$\Delta e^*$}&{$\Delta r^*$}&{$\Delta l^*$}&{$\Delta p^*$} &{$VSO$}&{$VVM$}&{$VCS$}&{$VSW$} \\
\midrule
Value &
{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\frac{8\alpha g}{16(1-\alpha)}$&$\frac{-8\beta\alpha g}{16(1-\alpha)}$&$\frac{\alpha g}{(1-\alpha)^2}$&$0$&
$\frac{\psi ^2-\phi ^2}{128k(1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{g\alpha\theta}{1-\alpha}+g\cs$&$\frac{\psi ^2-\phi ^2+32\alpha k(\psi-\phi)}{256k(1-\alpha)^2}$&$0$&$ \frac{3(\psi ^2-\phi ^2)+256\alpha k g[\alpha k+(1-\alpha)\theta]}{256k(1-\alpha)^2}+g\cs$\\
&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
0&0&0&0&$g[\frac{(\omega-\alpha k)\alpha}{2(1-\alpha)^2}-\frac{\alpha\theta}{1-\alpha}+\cs]$&$0$&$0$&$g[\frac{(\omega-\alpha k)\alpha}{2(1-\alpha)^2}-\frac{\alpha\theta}{1-\alpha}+\cs]$\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\end{table*}
\begin{prop} \label{prop:values_decision}
Given $d, k, \theta$: $e^{IG}>e^I$, $r^{IG}<r^I$, $l^{IG}>l^I$ if and only if $\cv<H(\alpha)$.
\end{prop}
\refprop{prop:values_decision} indicates three points.
Firstly, for given $d, k, \theta$, the launch insurance subsidy provided by the government can help to improve the successful launch probability $e$ which is definitely helps to promote the benign development of the commercial satellite industry.
Secondly, when the subsidy also helps to decrease the launch insurance rate $r$.
This is because insurance companies set insurance rates based on break-even, so the larger the $e$, the smaller the $r$.
From a market perspective, government subsidies help soften the insurance market.
Thirdly, the launch price in model IG also higher than that in model I.
This is attributed to the fact that SO is more willing to pay higher launch fees after receiving subsidies.
Higher launch fees also give VM an incentive to increase the probability of successful launches, thus forming a virtuous circle that helps to promote the development of the commercial satellite launch market.
Note, the above phenomenon occurs only in condition $\cv<H(\alpha)$ which means that when the SO chooses an expensive vehicle, $\cv>H(\alpha)$, government subsidies will not be able to form the above positive feedback closed loop in the market.
\begin{prop} \label{prop:values_profit}
\begin{enumerate}[(i)]
\item Given d, k, $\theta$: $\pgs>\pis$, $SW^{IG}>SW^I$.\par
\item Given d, k, $\theta$: $\pgv>\piv$ if and only if $\cv<H(\alpha)$.
\end{enumerate}
\end{prop}
\refprop{prop:values_profit} indicates two points.
Firstly, for given $d, k, \theta$, the profit of SO and the social welfare in model IG are always higher than in model I.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
This means that when the launch insurance subsidy program is implemented, satellite operators and society always benefit.
Mainly because the satellite operator is a direct beneficiary.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
Her earnings decided by the tradeoff between higher launch fees and higher launch success rates.
Secondly, the profit of VM in model IG is higher than in model I if and only if $\cv<H(\alpha)$.
The change of VM's profit depends on the tradeoff between higher effort cost and higher launch service income.
However, when the cost of vehicle is quite high, VM will not benefit from the government subsidy.
As a remark, it is not always preferred to implement the government subsidy in all cases.
When the government provides subsidies, it is necessary to screen satellite vendors, and only by subsidizing satellite launch activities with inexpensive vehicles can effectively promote the benign development of the launch market.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
Otherwise, subsidies can only increase the profit of satellite operators, but can not promote the launch success rate, which is not conducive to the optimal allocation of government funds.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
\section{The case with blockchain technology }
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
% \begin{table*}[htbp]
% \scriptsize
% % \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
% \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
% \caption{\label{tab:modelbg_decisions} The equilibrium outcomes in Model BG.}
% \centering
% \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
% \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{c}@{}}
% \toprule
% & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ } \\
% \midrule
% Effort of VM exerting $e^*$&
% $\frac{\lambda }{16 (1-\alpha )\kb}$ &
% $\frac{\mu-\alpha \kb }{(1-\alpha)\kb}$ \\
% Launch price $l^*$&
% $l^*=l_{S}=\frac{\lambda-8\theta(1-\alpha)}{8(1-\alpha)^2}$&
% $ l^*=l_{VA}= \frac{2\mu-2\alpha \kb-(1-\alpha) \theta}{(1-\alpha)^2}$\\
% Retail price $p^*$&
% $\frac{1+d+b}{2}$&
% $\frac{1+d+b}{2}$\\
% Premium rate $r^*$&
% $\beta(1-\frac{\lambda}{16(1-\alpha)\kb})$&
% $\beta\frac{k-\mu}{(1-\alpha)\kb}$\\
% SO's profit $\pbgs$&
% $\frac{\lambda^2}{128(1-\alpha)^2\kb}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)} -(1-g) \cs-\csb$&
% $\frac{(\mu-\alpha \kb)(\lambda+8\alpha \kb-8\mu)}{4(1-\alpha )^2\kb}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-(1-g)\cs-\csb$\\
% VM's profit $\pbgv$&
% $\frac{\lambda^2+32\alpha \kb\lambda}{256(1-\alpha)^2\kb}-\frac{ \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-\cv-\cvb$&
% $0$\\
% Consumer surplus $CS^{BG}$&
% $\frac{(1+d+b)^2}{8}$&
% $\frac{(1+d+b)^2}{8}$&\\
% Social welfare $SW^{BG}$&
% $\frac{3\lambda^2+32\alpha \kb\lambda}{256(1-\alpha)^2\kb}- \frac{\theta[1-(1-g)\alpha]}{1-\alpha}\theta-(1-g)\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb+\frac{(1+d+b)^2}{8}$&
% $\frac{(\mu-\alpha \kb)(\lambda+8\alpha \kb-8\mu)}{4(1-\alpha )^2\kb}+\frac{(1-g)\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-(1-g)\cs-\csb+\frac{(1+d+b)^2}{8}$\\
% \bottomrule
% \end{tabular}
% \begin{tablenotes}
% \item To avoid complicated writing, we define
% $\lambda=(1-\alpha)(1+d+b)^2+4(1-\alpha)\theta-8\alpha \kb(1-g)$,
% $\mu=\sqrt{(1-\alpha)^2\kb \cv+\alpha ^2{\kb}^2-(1-\alpha)\kb \theta}$.
% \end{tablenotes}
% \end{table*}
%
%
After exploring model I and model IG, we find that government subsidies for launch insurance do not benefit customers that the data demand $D$ and retail price $p$ remain unchanged in these two models.
However, the implementation of innovative technology, blockchain technology (BCT), injects new blood into the commercial space industry in two aspects:
on one hand, BCT can enhance the security of satellite data;
on the other hand, blockchain technology helps to improve the workflow efficiency of launch activities which helps to reduce the error rate, and thus increases the probability of successful launch.
In this section, we analytical exploring how BCT improve the performance of the satellite launch supply chain.
In the real world, as depicted in \reffig{fig:blockchain}, the launching workflow is supported by BCT to deal with the complexities such as contracts, order tracking, parts assembly, shipments, design and test documents, test results data, near real-time data, workflows for approvals, auditing, launch and control.
That means it will improve the data flow between different participants and capture the problem in time during the process.
In other words, when information is shared adequately in the whole supply chain, it will help VM to save the effort cost to reach the ideal launch success probability, which is related to the symmetric and transparent information.
(such as IBM and Cloud Constellation Corporation are working together to build a range of prototype solutions from Edge Computing in Space to exploring how blockchain can optimize the logistics and supply chain for the space tech industry \citep{Altaf2019}. \par
% TODO: \usepackage{graphicx} required
\begin{figure}[H]
\centering
\includegraphics[width=0.7\linewidth]{blockchain}
\caption{Satellite launch supported by blockchain platform.} \cite{Altaf2019}
\label{fig:blockchain}
\end{figure}
\subsection{Model IB: Blockchain-embedded satellite launch supply chain with insurance }
Compared to the case under Model I, all these parties will work together on the blockchain platform and the workflow will be more efficient which will be like
(i) Launch data is made accessible via application program interfaces (APIs) for each of the participants on the nodes, and all interactions such as data download are tracked.
(ii) All of the above activity is logged in the form of transactions in an immutable ledger database for auditing purposes to all the authorized interested participants.
(iii) The data collected by the satellite will also record on BCT which cannot be tampered with.
\reffig{fig:blockchain} shows the whole launch success process in the avail of blockchain.
Thus, the obvious advantage over Model I is that the transform data flow will decrease the effort cost and enhance the trust of customers.
In other words, for the members in the supply chain, for the effort cost VM exerting to improve the launch successfully probability (denoted by $k^B e^2$ for the case under Model IB), it will be lower under Model B than under Model I.
We assume the blockchain platform provided by the third party which will charge SO and VM for $\csb$ and $\cvb$ respectively.
For customers, the benefits brought by BCT are characterized by factor $b$ which will increase their utility.
To be specific, the market demand can be written as follows:
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:igd}
% \left\{
\begin{aligned}
D^{B} &= 1 \int_{p^{B}-d-b}^{1}{f\left( u \right) \mathrm{d} u}= 1-p^{B}+d+b \\
\end{aligned}
% \right.
\end{eqnarray}
Similar to \refsec{sec:modeli}, as the Stackelberg leader, SO sets the contract terms and the VM, as the follower, decides whether to accept the contract.
Once the cooperation is signed, each of the participants gets a node which has a copy of ledger and smart contracts.
As in \refsec{sec:modeli}, the SO prepays the supplier part of the contract price $\alpha*l$ ahead. After launching, she will pay $(1-\alpha)*l$ upon successful delivery and pays $0$ otherwise.
Concerning risk, SO buy the launch insurance with premium rate $r$ to compensate the damage if launch failed.
Therefore, the members' payoffs can be measured as follows:
\begin{eqnarray}
\begin{aligned}
\pbs &= epD -[\alpha + e(1-\alpha) ]l - r (\cs + \alpha l) + (1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l)- \cs-\csb,\label{eq:bso:payoff}\\
\pi_i^{B}&= r (\cs + \alpha l)-(1-e)\beta (\cs + \alpha l),\\
\pbv&=[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha) ]l - (1 - e) \theta - (\kb e^2 + \cv)-\cvb,\label{eq:bvm:payoff}\\
s.t.~\pbv &\geq 0
\end{aligned}
\end{eqnarray}
As shown, $\pbs$ consists of five parts:
(1) the income she will obtain once the satellite works in orbit ($e pD$),
(2) the launch service price ($[\alpha+e(1-\alpha)]l$),
(3) the premium SO pays for launch insurance($ \rb (\cs + \alpha l) $),
(4) the compensate she will get once the launch failed($(1-e) \beta(\cs + \alpha l)$),
(5) the cost of satellite and blockchain service, $\cs$ and $\csb$.
%Without loss of generality, the satellite income covers its whole cost; i.e., the SO sets a contract only when $F\geq\cs + \csb+\pb $.\par
After receiving a contract with price $l$ that is acceptable to VM, the cooperation is reached and a smart contract will be built.
Then VM gets the node of checking the contract, which captures serious details to direct the conduction design, development, test and evaluation efficiently which cost $\cv+\cvb$. Also, he will get the prepayment $\alpha*l$ from the SO.
If the vehicle launch successfully, he receives the last $(1-\alpha )*l$ from the SO. If launching is not successful, the VM receives no payment.
As shown, $\pbv$ consists of three parts:
(1)the prepaid income and expected gain upon successful launch $[\alpha + e (1 - \alpha)]l$,
(2)the expected loss of failure penalty in the event of launch failure $(1 - e) \theta$,
(3)the whole cost $\kb e^2 + \cv+\cvb$.
The non-negative profit constraint ensures the profitability of launch; otherwise, the VM will reject such a contract.
%As our model is mainly motivated to made-to-order vehicle, we assume that, once the rocket manufacture is accomplished, the VM has to launch the SO's satellite. Therefore, without loss of generality, we normalize his outside option to 0; i.e., the manufacturer accepts a contract only when $\pbv \geq 0$.\par
After a backward induction similar to the \ref{sec:modeli}, we obtain \reflem{lemma:modelb}.
\begin{lem} \label{lemma:modelb}
The equilibrium outcomes of Model IB are shown in \reftab{tab:modelb_decisions}.
\end{lem}
\begin{table*}[htbp]
\scriptsize
% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
\newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
\caption{\label{tab:modelb_decisions} The equilibrium outcomes in Model B.}
\centering
\renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
\begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{c}@{}}
\toprule
& \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } & \multicolumn{1}{c}{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ } \\
\midrule
Effort of VM exerting $e^*$&
$\frac{\eta }{16 (1-\alpha )\kb}$ &
$\frac{\mu-\alpha \kb }{(1-\alpha)\kb}$ \\
Launch price $l^*$&
$l^*=l_{S}=\frac{\eta-8\theta(1-\alpha)}{8(1-\alpha)^2}$&
$ l^*=l_{VA}= \frac{2\mu-2\alpha \kb-(1-\alpha) \theta}{(1-\alpha)^2}$\\
Retail price $p^*$&
$\frac{1+d+b}{2}$&
$\frac{1+d+b}{2}$\\
Premium rate $r^*$&
$\beta(1-\frac{\eta}{16(1-\alpha)\kb})$&
$\beta\frac{k-\mu}{(1-\alpha)\kb}$\\
SO's profit $\pbs$&
$\frac{\eta^2}{128(1-\alpha)^2\kb}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)} -\c-\csb$&
$\frac{(\mu-\alpha \kb)(\eta+8\alpha \kb-8\mu)}{4(1-\alpha )^2\kb}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-\cs-\csb$\\
VM's profit $\pbv$&
$\frac{\eta^2+32\alpha \kb\eta}{256(1-\alpha)^2\kb}-\frac{ \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-\cv-\cvb$&
$0$\\
Consumer surplus $CS^B$&
$\frac{(1+d+b)^2}{8}$&
$\frac{(1+d+b)^2}{8}$&\\
Social welfare $SW^B$&
$\frac{3\eta^2+32\alpha \kb\eta}{256(1-\alpha)^2\kb}- \theta-\cs-\cv-\csb-\cvb+\frac{(1+d+b)^2}{8}$&
$\frac{(\mu-\alpha \kb)(\phi+8\alpha \kb-8\mu)}{4(1-\alpha )^2\kb}+\frac{\alpha \theta}{(1-\alpha)}-\cs-\csb+\frac{(1+d+b)^2}{8}$\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\begin{tablenotes}
\item To avoid complicated writing, we define
$\eta=(1-\alpha)(1+d+b)^2+4(1-\alpha)\theta-8\alpha \kb$,
$\mu=\sqrt{(1-\alpha)^2\kb \cv+\alpha ^2{\kb}^2-(1-\alpha)\kb \theta}$.
\end{tablenotes}
\end{table*}
Outcomes in \reflem{lemma:modelb} are neat and similar to \reflem{lemma:modeli}.
There are two differences worth knowing.
(i) First, when $\cv<H(\alpha)$,as $\kb$ is less than $k$, leading to $\eta>\phi$, thus the successful launch probability, the launch price are higher than in model I; and the premium rate is lower than in Model I.
(ii) When $\cv\geq H(\alpha)$, the equilibrium outcomes are not neat and cannot be directly compared which we will conduct analyze in detail in \refsec{sec:value_b}.
(iii) Although the retail price is higher compared with model I, the consumer surplus in increase with the implementation of BCT.
Notedly, the consumer surplus is only related to $b$, not to the cost of the blockchain.
Therefore, as long as blockchain technology is adopted, the consumer surplus can be improved.
As the sensitivity outcomes shown in \reftab{tab:modeli_and_ig_sensitivity} we now conduct the analysis.
\begin{table*}[htbp]
\scriptsize
% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
\newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
\caption{\label{tab:modeli_and_b_sensitivity} Sensitivity analyses for Model I and Model IB.}
\centering
\renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
\begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}}
\toprule
& {Model}&{Situation}&{$e^*$}&{$r^*$}&{$l^*$}&{$p^*$} &{$\pi_S$}&{$\pi_V$}&{$CS$}&{$SW$} \\
\midrule
$d \uparrow$ &
Model I &{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
-&-&-&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
&Model IB& {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
-&-&-&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
$k \uparrow$ &
Model I &{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$: $k<k_1$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$\\
&&&&&&&$\uparrow :k\geq k_1$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$}
&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$-$&$\downarrow$\\
&Model IB& {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\downarrow $&$-$&$\downarrow$: $k<k_3$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\downarrow$\\
&&&&&&&$\uparrow :k\geq k_3$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$\\
$\theta \uparrow$&
Model I &{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow: \theta<\theta_{V1}$&$-$&$\uparrow: \theta<\theta_{W1}$\\
&&&&&&&&$\downarrow: \theta \geq \theta_{V1}$&&$\downarrow: \theta \geq \theta_{W1}$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$}&
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$-$&$\uparrow$\\
&Model IB& {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\downarrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow: \theta<\theta_{V3}$&$-$&$\uparrow: \theta<\theta_{W3}$\\
&&&&&&&&$\downarrow: \theta \geq \theta_{V3}$&&$\downarrow: \theta \geq \theta_{W3}$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$}&
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$-$&$\uparrow$\\
$b \uparrow$&
Model IB& {$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\uparrow$&$\downarrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
&&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$}&
$-$&$-$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$-$&$-$&$\uparrow$&$\uparrow$\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\end{table*}
By comparing the sensitivity analysis results of model IB and model I, we find three differences:
(i) Firstly, if the effort cost coefficient increase, when $\cv<H(\alpha)$, there there exist a threshold $k_3$, where $k_3=\frac{(1-\alpha)[(1+b+d)^2+4\theta]}{8\alpha}$.
Thus SO's profit decreases as $k^B$ increasing when $k^B<k_3$, otherwise $\pgs$ decreases.
Note $k_3>k_2$, which means BCT raises the threshold of the SO to change the trend of her profits.
(ii) Secondly, if the failed-launch penalty$\theta$ increase, when $\cv<H(\alpha)$, the thresholds of VM's profit $\theta_{V3}$ and social welfare $\theta_{W3}$ also change, where $\theta_{V3}=\frac{32\kb-(1-\alpha)(1+d+b)^2-8\alpha \kb}{4(1-\alpha)}$ and $\theta_{W3}=\frac{32\kb-3(1-\alpha)(1+d+b)^2-24\alpha \kb}{12(1-\alpha)}$.
It is worth noting that the implementation of blockchain technology actually reduces the threshold of punishment to change the profit trend which means that the penalty tolerated by the VM and society is reduced, that is, once $\theta>\theta_{V3}$ and $\theta>\theta_{W3}$ both profits of them will decrease.
(iii) If the benefits that blockchain brings to consumers $b$ increases,
(a) when $\cv<H(\alpha)$, the successful launch probabilit, launch price, retail price, member's profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare will all increase; the premium rate will decrease;
(b) when $\cv<H(\alpha)$, although the retail price increase and the consumer surplus obtain for the customers will increase at all.
In order to figure out the conditions for implementing BCT, we conduct the value study in \refsec{sec:value_b}.
\subsection{Values of implying BCT}
\label{sec:value_b}
After deriving the equilibrium decisions in the supply chains under Models I and B, we now explore the values of blockchain technology.
By comparing the equilibrium outcomes model I and model IB, we obtain the following results:
\begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:values_b}
\begin{aligned}
VSO^B&=\pbs-\pis\\
VVM^B&=\pbv-\piv\\
VCS^B&=CS^{IB}-CS^I\\
VSW^B&=SW^{IB}-SW^I\\
\end{aligned}
\end{eqnarray}
We report the results in \reftab{tab:values_decision_b} and \reftab{tab:values_profit_b} by comparing the equilibrium outcomes between model I and model IB.
After analyzing the results, we obtain \refprop{prop:values_decision_b} and \refprop{prop:values_profit_b}.
\begin{table*}[htbp]
\scriptsize
% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
\newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
\caption{\label{tab:values_decision_b} Values of BCT.}
\centering
\renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
\begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}}
\toprule
&{Situation}&{$\Delta e^*$}&{$\Delta r^*$}&{$\Delta l^*$}&{$\Delta p^*$} \\
\midrule
Value &
{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\frac{k\eta-\kb \phi}{16k\kb(1-\alpha)}>0$&
$-\beta\frac{k\eta-\kb \phi}{16k\kb(1-\alpha)}<0$&
$\frac{k\eta-\kb \phi+8\theta(1-\alpha)(\kb-k)}{16k\kb(1-\alpha)}>0$&
$\frac{b}{2}>0$\\
&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
$\frac{k\mu-\kb( \omega -\alpha)}{k\kb(1-\alpha)}>0$&
$-\beta$$\frac{k\mu-\kb \omega}{k\kb(1\alpha)}<0$&
$\frac{2(\mu-\omega)+2\alpha(k-\kb)}{(1-\alpha)^2}>0$&
$\frac{b}{2}>0$\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\end{table*}
\begin{table*}[htbp]
\scriptsize
% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
\newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
\caption{\label{tab:values_profit_b} Values of BCT.}
\centering
\renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
\begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{1pt}}l*{14}{l}@{}}
\toprule
&{Situation}&{$VSO^B$}&{$VVM^B$}&{$VCS^B$}&{$VSW^B$} \\
\midrule
Value &
{$\cv < H(\alpha)$ } &
$\frac{k\eta ^2-\kb \phi^2}{128k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}-\csb$&
$\frac{k\eta ^2-\kb \phi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\eta-\phi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}-\cvb$&
$\frac{b^2+2b(1+d)}{8}$&
$\frac{3k\eta ^2-3\kb \phi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\eta-\phi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b(1+d)}{8}-\csb-\cvb$\\
&{$\cv \geq H(\alpha)$ }&
$\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}-\csb$&
$0$&
$\frac{b^2+2b(1+d)}{8}$&
$\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}+\frac{b^2+2b(1+d)}{8}-\csb$\\
\bottomrule
\end{tabular}
\end{table*}
\begin{prop} \label{prop:values_decision_b}
Given $d$, $\kb$, $k$, $\theta$: $e^{IB}>e^I$, $r^{IB}<r^I$, $l^{IB}>l^I$, $p^{IB}>p^I$.
\end{prop}
\refprop{prop:values_decision_b} gives us four claims.
Firstly, the optimal effort exerted by VM is higher after applying blockchain technology, which leads to a higher launch success probability directly.
That also implies that blockchain technology helps to improve the work efficiency.
Secondly, premium rate is going down. This is because the successful launch probability increase which is beneficial for SO.
Thirdly, the launch price is higher with the support of BCT, mainly because the probability of successful launch increases, and the SO is willing to pay higher fees
Fourthly, as shown the change of $e$, $r$, and $l$ are similar to \ref{eq:values_g}, however, the retail price in model B increases after implementing BCT which is different from \ref{eq:values_g}.
It is due to the higher utility that BCT bring to customers, so they are more willing to pay a higher retail price.
\begin{prop} \label{prop:values_profit_b}
Given $d$, $\kb$, $k$, $\theta$:
\begin{enumerate}[(i)]
\item
If $\csb ~ \big( \begin{smallmatrix} < \\ =\\> \end{smallmatrix} \big)~ \min\{\frac{k\eta ^2-\kb \phi^2}{128k\kb (1-\alpha)^2},\frac{k(\mu-\alpha \kb)[\eta-8(\mu-\alpha \kb)]-\kb (\omega-\alpha k)[\phi-8(\omega-\alpha k)]}{4k\kb(1-\alpha)^2}\}$,
then we have: $VSO^B~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~0$;
\item
When $\cv <H(\alpha)$, if $\cvb~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} < \\ =\\> \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~\frac{k\eta ^2-\kb \phi^2+32\alpha k \kb(\eta-\phi)}{256k\kb (1-\alpha)^2} $ , for $\cv <H(\alpha$)
then we have: $VVM^B~ \big(\begin{smallmatrix} > \\ =\\< \end{smallmatrix} \big) ~ 0$;
when $\cv \geq H(\alpha)$, $VVM^B \equiv 0$
\item
$VCS^B>0$
\end{enumerate}
\end{prop}
Proposition \ref{prop:values_profit_b} shows three neat findings.
Firstly, it gives the threshold of blockchain cost, which indicate that if the cost of implementing blockchain technology is high, then launching through the BCT platform is not profitable for the SO.
That is because the loss of paying for blockchain cannot be offset by the benefits of improving the quality of data flow.
Actually, there are two thresholds for the SO to decide whether implement BCT in two situations.
However, once the cost of BCT is quite low, it is always profitable for the SO to use blockchain.
Secondly, it also gives the threshold for VM using blockchain.
When $\cv<H(\alpha)$, if the cost of BCT is low, there is space for VM to make profit.
However, when $\cv$ is high, it is no use for VM to apply BCT.
It lies in the launch price SO offering only matches VM's acceptance level and his payoff being zero in this situation.
Thirdly, with the help of BCT, the consumer surplus increase which means customers will benefit more although they have to pay higher retail price.
\section{Conclusions}\label{sec:conclusions}
%\subsection{Remarkble findings}
Nowadays, with the prosperity of commercial launch, more and more research study the operation management in space.
Motivated by the real-world government-subsidized launch insurance project, we explored the operations of the satellite launch supply chain with government-subsidized insurance.
Firstly, we established the traditional insurance model and the government-subsidized insurance model.
By deriving analytical results, we demonstrate the optimal decisions for each participant.
We have further uncovered the effect of the subsidies on different variables.
Finally, we built value models to investigate the benefit of subsidies, especially revealing the conditions under which one model outperforms the other.
However, we find that if only the government launch subsidy program the customers cannot be benefit .
So we investigate the blockchain applications in the space launch supply chain by building blockchain-embedded insurance model which is also be implemented in the real world.
As a concluding remark, we highlight the answers as follows:
\begin{enumerate} [(1)]
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
\item When government subsidies for the selection of satellite operators for low-cost vehicle launches, it helps to form positive feedback in the commercial satellite market,
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
that is, the satellite vendor is more willing to pay high launch prices, so that the vehicle manufacture have the motivation to increase the probability of successful launches.
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
\item Once the government subsidy project is launched, the satellite operator will always get more from it than before.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
But for the vehicle manufacturer, only when the cost of vehicle is relatively low, his income will increase compared to before; otherwise, he cannot benefit from the subsidy program.
For consumers, there is no change in consumer surplus.
Therefore, the overall social welfare as the sum of the profit of the various subjects will increase.
\item In the blockchain-embedded model, the values that blockchain bring to the optimal decisions are similar to the government subsidy brings.
However, there is one difference to claim that the retail price has been increased and the market demand also increases.
\item Moreover, for the satellite, she will always benefit from the adoption of blockchain if its cost is relatively low.
\item However, the profitable condition for the vehicle to decide whether use the blockchain is not only the cost of blockchain is expensive but also the cost of vehicle manufacturing is low.
\item Significantly, the use of the blockchain launch platform will make the consumer surplus increase no matter in which situation.
\end{enumerate}
%\subsection{Managerial implications}
2022-06-14 19:20:33 +08:00
%Analyzing the derived findings, we further propose the following managerial implications, which help form the action plans for satellite operators and vehicle manufacturers and the government.\par
%Satellite operator: We have highlighted that government subsidy is critical in improving profit for satellite operators. Moreover, the adoption of the blockchain-embedded launch platform will enhance the profit. .\par
%Vehicle manufacturer: The blockchain-embedded launch platform will help to motivate the manufacturer to exert more effort to improve the launch success probability based on sharing data. However, the best strategy for the manufacture is adopting blockchain technology when cooperating with high anti-risk satellite operator. In that way, they could make it a win-win.
2022-06-13 21:16:40 +08:00
\section{ Future research}
For the future studies, we suggest several probable future directions.
First, the risk attitude of different participants can be taken into account which will effect the optimal decisions.
Second, the JIT operation management with the supported of blockchain in launch supply chain can be promising directions for future research.
Last but not least, multi-tier supply chain or supply chain network will be interesting to investigate, which involve more members such as the rideshare broker in piggyback launch and rideshare or cluster launch \citep{Barschke2020}.
% A table containing numbers is more complex. \reftab{tab:result} shows how to add a wide table with different alignments. It is suggested that use an Excel plugin ``Excel2LaTeX.xla'' to create a data table.
% \begin{table*}[htbp]
% \scriptsize
%% \hspace*{-1cm} % apply this to move the table left, so that the right part of a wide table can be shown.
% \newcommand{\tabincell}[2]{\begin{tabular}{@{}#1@{}}#2\end{tabular}}
% \caption{\label{tab:result} Experimental results for the data sets \textit{Random} and \textit{Circles}.}
% \centering
% \renewcommand{\arraystretch}{1.3}
% \begin{tabular}{@{\extracolsep{2pt}}l*{14}{r}@{}}
% \toprule
% \multirow{2}*{Index}
% & \multicolumn{7}{c}{Random}
% & \multicolumn{7}{c}{Circles}\\
% \cline{2-8}\cline{9-15}
% & \multicolumn{1}{c}{20} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{60} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{100} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{200} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{300} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{400} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{500} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{20} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{60} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{100} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{200} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{300} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{400} & \multicolumn{1}{c}{500}\\
% \midrule
% $z_1$ & 0.85 & 0.6 & 0.53 & 0.44 & 0.41 & 0.42 & 0.41 & 0.6 & 0.45 & 0.43 & 0.41 & 0.39 & 0.4 & 0.38\\
% $z_2$ & 0.85 & 0.46 & 0.51 & 0.4 & 0.39 & 0.4 & 0.37 & 0.45 & 0.42 & 0.38 & 0.38 & 0.37 & 0.37 & 0.37\\
% \bottomrule
% \end{tabular}
% \end{table*}
%
% \section{Math}
% In-text equations like $a_{ij,t} \sim N(75, 25^2)$. For multiple equations, use \textit{eqnarray} and \& to align.
% \begin{equation}\label{equ:utility}
% U_{ij,t} = \left(\frac{W^{min}_{i,t}}{W_{ij,t}} \right)^{1-\beta}\cdot \left( \frac{Q_{j,t}}{Q^{max}_{t}} \right) ^{\beta},
% \end{equation}
% where
% \begin{eqnarray}
% \label{equ:maxtau} W^{\min}_{i,t}&=&\min \{W_{ij,t}\}^N_{j=1}, \\
% \label{equ:minfq} Q^{\max}_{t}&=&\max \{Q_{j,t}\}^N_{j=1}.
% \end{eqnarray}\par
% \begin{eqnarray}\label{eq:B5}
% \left\{
% \begin{aligned}
% &\frac{\partial \pi_1}{\partial p_1}
% = \dfrac{Qe^{b-ap_1}}{\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}}
% + \dfrac{a(c_1-p_1)Qe^{b-ap_1}}{\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}}
% - \dfrac{a(c_1-p_1)Qe^{2(b-ap_1)}}{\big(\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}\big)^2} = 0,\\
% &\dots,\\
% &\frac{\partial \pi_n}{\partial p_n}
% = \dfrac{Qe^{b-ap_n}}{\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}}
% + \dfrac{a(c_n-p_n)Qe^{b-ap_n}}{\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}}
% - \dfrac{a(c_n-p_n)Qe^{2(b-ap_n)}}{\big(\displaystyle \sum_{f\in \mathcal{F}} e^{b-a p_f}\big)^2} = 0.
% \end{aligned}
% \right.
% \end{eqnarray}
% \begin{equation}\label{equ:if}
% f(x)=
% \begin{cases}
% \frac{x^2-x}{x},& \text{if } x\geq 1\\
% 0, & \text{otherwise}
% \end{cases}
% \end{equation}
%
% \section{Citation}
% Use \textbackslash{citet} when the authors are the subject of a sentence; otherwise use \textbackslash{citep}. For example, \citet{1929-Hotelling-p41-57} has spurred voluminous subsequent research on this topic... The term O2O originally means that the customer enjoys the product or service offline through buying online \citep{2010-Rampell-p-}. By means of agent-based modelling (ABM), the CAS theory can be applied to study various complex systems such as ecosystems, supply networks, financial markets, economies, and social systems \citep[see, e.g., ][]{2009-Farmer-p685-686, 2016-Chandrasekaran-p390-416}.\par
%
%
% \section{Conclusion}\label{sec:conclusion}
% The conclusion goes here.\par
%
%
% \section*{Acknowledgement}
% Dong was supported in part by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71573244, 71532013, 71202115 and 71403260). The authors acknowledge Mr. XXX for providing useful data and suggestions. The authors greatly appreciate the editor and anonymous referees for their comments, which helped to improve this paper.
%
% \appendix
% \section{Pseudo Codes}\label{sec:apd:code}
% \subsection{The procedure}
% Algorithm \refalg{alg:CIPS} shows a piece of pseudo code.\par
% \begin{figure}%[!t]
% % \removelatexerror
% \begin{algorithm}[H]
% \caption{The CIPS generation procedure}\label{alg:CIPS}
% \KwData{A set $Y$ containing $n$ demand points with ($x$, $y$) coordinates and coverage radius $R$.}
% \KwResult{A set $C$ consisting of intersection points and demand points with their coordinates.}
% % initialize population $P = \left \{ X_{1}, ... , X_{N} \right \} $\;
% Create a temporary set copied from $Y$\;
% \For( \emph{loop $Y$}){$i$ in range($n$)}
% {
% \For( \emph{loop $Y$}){$j$ in range($n$)}
% {
% $d_{i,j} =$ distance between $Y_i$ and $Y_j$\;
% \If{$0 < d_{i,j}\leq2R$ }
% {
% Calculate the coordinates of intersection points\;
% Add generated IPs to the temporary set\;
% }
% }
% }
% Return the temporary set as $C$\;
% \end{algorithm}
% \end{figure}
%
% \newpage
%% \section*{References}
\bibliographystyle{model5-names-with-volume-number}
% \bibliographystyle{IEEEtran}
%\bibliographystyle{ACM-Reference-Format}
\bibliography{SAVM}
\end{document}